The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: VPugazhenthi Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_S Date:1/4/
09 Time:15:23:36 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/
revises/9781405132879_4_S.3d


over succeeding generations: urbanization
is both the outcome of social stratification
and a means wherebyhegemonyis perpetu-
ated. Themorphologyof pre-industrial cities
reflects this interdependence between social
and spatial order:poweris consolidated by
the ruling class through its residential location
in the city centre, the most protected and
most accessible district. Here, residents forge
a social solidarity based on their literacy,
access to the surplus (which is stored in the
central area of the city), and shared upper-
class culture, which includes distinctive
manners and patterns of speech. Elite cluster-
ing in the city centre is reinforced by the lack
of rapid transportation.
The privileged central district is surrounded
by haphazardly arranged neighbourhoods
housing the lower class. Households in these
areas are sorted by occupation/income (mer-
chants near the centre, followed by minor bur-
eaucrats, artisans and, finally, the unskilled),
ethnic origin and extended family networks.
Merchants are generally not accorded elite
status, since power is achieved through reli-
gious and military control, while trade is
viewed with suspicion. The model is less
clear on the residential placement of outcast
groups (typically slaves and other conquered
peoples): some of these perform service roles
and are intermingled with the rest of the urban
population, while others live at the extreme
periphery of the city – frequently beyond its
walls.
In formulating this model, Sjoberg reverses
the logic used by Burgess – who placed com-
mercial activities at the centre of the city, and a
succession of poor through wealthy residential
districts around it. Sjoberg notes that the
Burgess model is applicable only to industrial
cities, where production and commerce propel
economic growth and where capitalists are
accorded high social standing. Further, he
argues that human ecology incorrectly treats
urbanization as an independent social force,
when in reality urban growth should be seen
as a ‘dependent variable’, as it depends on the
distribution of social power, and on available
technology. Empirical investigations of the
Sjoberg model have been generally supportive,
but caution that the model cannot account for
the intricate details of urban development
across different cultural contexts. Others have
criticized the theoretical content of Sjoberg’s
work, especially his stress on the role of tech-
nology and his uncritical view of social power.
Sjoberg’s functionalist logic (which blurs dis-
tinctions between causes and consequences),

however, remains largely unnoticed and
unchallenged (seefunctionalism). dh

Suggested reading
Carter (1983); Langton (1975); Ley (1983);
Morris (1994); Radford (1979); Wheatley (1963).

skid row Essentially a North American
term, ‘skid row’ traditionally referred to areas
characterized by concentrations of rooming
houses and accommodation for single men
working in the timber industry: over time,
the term has become a more general short-
hand for areas wherehomelessnessis evident.
Often offering hostel or temporary accommo-
dation, skid rows are thus notorious as spaces
of rough sleeping, with temporary pavement
encampments or ‘cardboard cities’ offering
refuge for those who congregate in these areas.
In the larger skid rows, intricatesocial net-
worksand relationships may develop within
the community, as well as between the
service-dependent and those service providers
who seek to assist them with welfare, alcohol,
drug andhealthissues (Rowe and Wolch,
1990). In many instances, dwellers of areas
described as skid row districts have fought to
contest this designation: despite this, the term
persists in the North American social imagin-
ation as a pejorative description of the social
margins of the city.
Studies by urban sociologists and geograph-
ers have suggested that the development of
skid row areas in North American cities has,
in some cases, been connected to policies of
containment designed to remove street home-
less populations from wealthier locales. Yet
currently the number of skid row districts is
declining markedly, as corporate gentrification
of the central city squeezes homeless popula-
tions from sites that they have sometimes
occupied for decades – see, for example,
Smith (1996b) on the forcible removal of the
homeless and itinerant population from
Tompkins Square Park, New York. In such
instances, anti-begging ordinances and zoning
laws have been used to disperse visible home-
less populations and ‘sanitize’ areas prior to
gentrification. Although the erasure of
such ‘landscapes of despair’ should not be a
cause for regret, it generates some significant
questions about how welfare providers
might best target resources to increasingly
dispersed homeless populations (Lee and
Price-Spratlen, 2004), as well as raising the
spectre of the increasedprivatizationofpub-
lic space. As such, the disappearance of skid
row areas is rarely taken as evidence of an

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_S Final Proof page 686 1.4.2009 3:23pm

SKID ROW
Free download pdf