The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_C Date:31/3/09
Time:21:45:53 Filepath://ppdys1108/BlackwellCup/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-
9781405132879/appln/3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_C.3d


declining both absolutely and relatively as
shops and offices move to more accessible
suburban locations (cf.edge city;retailing;
sprawl). rj

Suggested reading
Carter (1995); Murphy (1972).

central place theory A theoretical statement
of the size and distribution of settlements
within anurban systemin which marketing –
especiallyretailingof goods and services – is
the predominant urban function. The theory
assumes that both customers and retailers are
utility-maximizers, making it anormative
statement against which actual patterns can
be compared.
Of the two separate central place theories
developed, Christaller’s (1933) has been most
influential. It was based on two concepts:the
range of a good– the maximum distance that
people will travel to buy it; andthe threshold for
a good– the minimum volume of sales neces-
sary for a viable establishment selling that
good (or a bundle of linked goods, such as
groceries). In order to maximize their utilities,
retailers locate establishments to be as near
their customers as possible and customers visit
the nearest available centre: in this way, expend-
iture ontransport costsis minimized and
spending on goods and services maximized.
On a uniform plane with a uniformly dis-
tributed population, Christaller showed that
application of these two concepts produced a
hexagonalnetworkof central places housing
the establishments, organized in a hierarchy
whose number of levels reflected the number
of goods/services with similar range and
threshold values (he identified seven). Each
was centrally located within itshinterland,
with those at the hierarchy’s lowest level hav-
ing the smallest number of establishments and
serving the smallest hinterlands, and thus
most widely distributed. The ways in which
smaller settlements nested within the hinter-
lands of larger ones depended on a further set
of principles. Christaller identified three (as
shown in the figure). Themarketing principle
(k¼3: a in the figure) minimizes the number
of settlements so that each is at the meeting-
point of three hexagonal hinterlands for
centres at the next hierarchical level up: the
number of centres in each order is 1, 2, 6, 18,
54, 162 and 486. According to thetransport
principle(k¼4: b in the figure) the goal is to
minimize the length of roads joining adjacent
places. Each settlement is located centrally
on the boundary line between the hexagonal

hinterlands of two places in the next highest
order hierarchy, and the number of centres is
in the ratio 1, 2, 8, 32, 128, 512 and 2,048.
Finally, theadministrative principle(k¼7: c in
the diagram) has each lower-order settlement
and its hinterland nested exclusively within the
hinterland of a single settlement in the next
highest order, producing a much larger num-
ber of places in the ratio 1, 6, 42, 294, 2,058,
14,406 and 100,842.
Lo ̈sch’s (1940) model was much less restrict-
ive than Christaller’s. Rather than bunch all
functions into seven ‘orders’ he treated each as
having a separate range, threshold and hex-
agonal hinterland. Where feasible, functions
were clustered into settlements but all central
places with certain functions in them need not –
asinChristaller’sscheme–alsocontain all ofthe
functions with smaller ranges and thresholds.
This produced a much wider range of settle-
ments in terms of size and complexity of busi-
ness profiles: whereas Christaller’s theory
produced a stepped hierarchical urban system,
Lo ̈sch’s was consistent with a more continuous
distribution of urban sizes.
Central place theory was a major stimulus to
work in the early years of geography’squanti-
tative revolution: it was described by Bunge
(1968, p. 133) as ‘geography’s finest intellec-
tual product’. Christaller’s work, in particular,
was the basis of much research into the size
and spacing of settlements and into consumer
behaviour (both inter- and intra-urban), and
also as the basis for planning settlement pat-
terns – not only in the anodyne cases of new
settlements in the Dutch polders and the dis-
tribution of new shopping centres in cities, but
also in the violent resettlement of Eastern
Europe as part of the Naziholocaust.
With greater mobility and customer choice
available in many, more developed, societies,
theunderlyingassumptionsare increasingly
irrelevant and the theory remains more as an
exemplar of modelling during that period
of geography’s history than as aparadigmfor
understanding contemporary settlement pat-
terns, although it is one of the theories ‘redis-
covered’ in thenew economic geography.
(See alsoperiodic market systems.) rj

Suggested reading
Beavon (1977); Berry and Parr (1988); Fujita,
Krugman and Venables (1999).

centrifugal and centripetal forces Terms
adapted from physics by C.C. Colby (1932)
to describe two counteracting forces generat-
ing intra-urban land-use changes. Centrifugal

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_C Final Proof page 76 31.3.2009 9:45pm

CENTRAL PLACE THEORY
Free download pdf