EDITOR’S PROOF
A Collective-Action Theory of Fiscal-Military State Building 55
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
1.3 Investment in fiscal centralization
First, notice that when fiscal capacity is centralized the ruler maximizes fiscal trans-
fers by choosing the socially optimal amountG∗. Each corporation faces the fol-
lowing participation constraint when the ruler proposes centralization:
v(xi,y) ̄ +θαiy(G,y) ̄ −t≥v(xˆi,y) ̄ +θαiy
(
f(g),ˆ y ̄
)
−ˆgi−ˆτi−ei. (4)
The right hand side of (4) is constant and given by the equilibrium policy pro-
file{ˆτ,x,ˆgˆ}. The corporations can refuse centralization and force the ruler to
keep fiscal capacity fragmented. Summing overn and solving fort, we ob-
tainnt≤
∑
i[v(xi,y) ̄ +θαiy(G,y) ̄]−C, whereCis a constant. It follows that
uCR(x, G)≤
∑
i[v(xi,y) ̄ +θαiy(G,y) ̄]−C−c(x, G)−F. Therefore, the ruler
sets the maximum upper bound on net fiscal transfers by choosingG∗as defined
in (3).
Two conditions must hold for fiscal centralization to occur. First, the participa-
tion constraint in (4) must hold for at leastn ̄corporations. The corporations can
refuse centralization and the ruler has no credible threat but to preserve fiscal frag-
mentation. Second, the ruler’s payoff must be higher under centralization than under
fragmentation. If the ruler’s payoff given the tax payment necessary to obtain com-
pliance fromn ̄corporations is less than the payoff from{ˆτ,x,ˆ gˆ}, the ruler does not
propose centralization.
Substituting in (4)for(τˆi,xˆi,g)ˆ and solving fortwe obtain the maximum tax
payment that each corporation is willing to pay in exchange for the optimal level of
the public good:
tiM≤v(xi,y) ̄ +θαi
[
y
(
G∗,y ̄
)
−y
(
f( 0 ,g−i),y ̄
)]
, fori= 1 ,...,n. (5)
A couple remarks about this maximum tax payment are in order. First, the ruler
obtains higher maximum payments from those corporations who benefit more from
the public good (αi). Second, the ruler can obtain compliance from corporationiat
a tax payment higher than the maximum in (5) by compensating with private goods
(a higherxi) or if the prospects of economic activity increase.
I first obtain the SPNE assuming the ruler can collect corporation-specific tax
payments and provides the socially optimal amount of private goodsx∗. The con-
straints in (5) bind for alli, otherwise the ruler would be able to increase his
payoff by increasing the tax payment for some corporations. Lett∗i ≡v(xi,y) ̄ +
θαi[y(G∗,y) ̄ −y(f ( 0 ,g−i),y) ̄]be the binding constraint in (5)fori. The follow-
ing proposition gives the condition under which policy profile{t∗,x∗,G∗}is an
equilibrium forn ̄=n, wheret∗=(t 1 ∗,...,tn∗).
Proposition 1At the SPNE,the ruler proposes policy profile{t∗,x∗,G∗},all cor-
porations accept and the ruler increases fiscal centralization if the probability of a
threat is such that:
θ≥
F+c(x∗,G∗)−[
∑
iei+c(x
∗,G)ˆ]
[Y(G∗,y) ̄ −Y(G,ˆ y) ̄]
∑
iαi/n
. (6)