The Language of Argument

(singke) #1
2 6 3

12


Choices


Probabilities are used not only when we determine what to believe but also when we


choose what to do. Although we sometimes assume that we know how our actions
will turn out, we often have to make decisions in the face of risk, when we do not
know what the outcomes of our options will be, but we do know the probabilities
of those outcomes. To help us assess reasoning about choices involving risk, this
chapter will explain the notions of expected monetary value and expected overall
value. Our most difficult choices arise, however, when we do not know even the
probabilities of various outcomes. Such decisions under ignorance or uncertainty
pose special problems, for which a number of rules have been proposed. Although
these rules are useful in many situations, their limitations will also be noted.

Expected Monetary Value


It is obvious that having some sense of probable outcomes is important for
running our lives. If we hear that there is a 95 percent chance of rain, this
usually provides a good enough reason to call off a picnic. But the exact
relationship between probabilities and decisions is complex and often
misunderstood.
The best way to illustrate these misunderstandings is to look at lotteries
in which the numbers are fixed and clear. A $1 bet in a lottery might make
you as much as $10 million. That sounds good. Why not take a shot at $10
million for only a dollar? Of course, there is not much chance of winning the
lottery—say, only 1 chance in 20 million—and that sounds bad. Why throw
$1 away on nothing? So we are pulled in two directions. What we want to
know is just how good the bet is. Is it, for example, better or worse than a
wager in some other lottery? To answer questions of this kind, we need to
introduce the notion of expected monetary value.
The idea of expected monetary value takes into account three features
that determine whether a bet is financially good or bad: the probability of
winning, the net amount you gain if you win, and the net amount you lose
if you lose. Suppose that on a $1 ticket there is 1 chance in 20 million of win-
ning the New York State Lottery, and you will get $10 million from the state
if you do. First, it is worth noticing that, if the state pays you $10 million,

97364_ch12_ptg01_263-272.indd 263 15/11/13 11:00 AM


some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materiallyCopyright 201^3 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights,
affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Free download pdf