Cultural Geography

(Nora) #1
These are undoubtedly important questions,
and their centrality within economic geography
in recent times has helped enliven the field con-
siderably (Barnes and Gertler, 1999; Clark et al.,
2000a; Lee and Wills, 1997; Sheppard and
Barnes, 2000).^1 It has also served to build valu-
able bridges to scholarship in other related fields,
such as economic sociology, industrial economics
and the study of material culture, where inter-
esting things have been happening recently.
However, the cultural turn in economic geo-
graphers’ study of production is already, in some
ways, old news.^2 The question now to be asked
is: what has it delivered? The answer I would
venture at this stage is: not as much as had been
promised or hoped for originally. For every
advance towards enlightenment there has been
an equal measure of confusion. While the intro-
duction of cultural arguments has greatly
enriched and enlivened the study of production
questions, it has also raised pressing new ques-
tions without answering them, and has left many
important older questions unanswered or
neglected. Because of this, some constructive
criticism concerning this larger project and its
progress thus far is appropriate.
In this chapter, my aim is to address these
developments by taking a sceptical view of what
has been achieved to this point. My purpose is
notto belittle or denigrate the important and use-
ful work that has been completed thus far, for I
agree wholeheartedly with Thrift (2000a) that,
thanks to the cultural turn, we can never again
look at ‘the economic’ in quite the same way –
nor should we. My goal is to challenge the sense
of self-satisfaction that has, in my view, perme-
ated the subdiscipline rather prematurely, by
posing some unsettling questions. I begin by
attempting to distil the recent ferment around the
cultural and its relationship to the economic (at
least in the realm of production)^3 into three big
ideas: the rediscovery of ‘the social’ in produc-
tion systems, the rise of the learning paradigm
and the idea of regional culture, and the evolu-
tionary dynamics of local production systems. I
then offer up a critical commentary on this
newish cultural economic geography, focusing
on several important areas of controversy. In par-
ticular, I argue that we have made surprisingly
little progress in advancing a plausible theoreti-
cal understanding of one of the most central
entities within capitalist production systems – the
firm. As a consequence, our ability to provide
useful answers to some very fundamental ques-
tions – like ‘When and why is the local important
in production and innovation processes?’ or
‘Under what circumstances does production
knowledge travel between places?’ – remains

very poorly developed. I conclude by enunciating
some other important questions that have been
neglected or left for dead, but which are still
pressing and in need of our serious attention.

A CULTURAL ECONOMIC
GEOGRAPHY OF PRODUCTION:
BIG IDEAS

Just where did this renewed interest by economic
geographers in the culture of production come
from? Why is the cultural seen as being so
important now? I think it is possible to answer
this by singling out key debates and questions at
several different scales of analysis. At the macro
scale, the tremendous interest and attention given
to the success of ‘Japan, Inc.’ during the 1980s
(Oliver and Wilkinson, 1988) and Germany’s
‘Rhineland model’ of stakeholder capitalism in
the 1990s (Hutton, 1995) has foregrounded what
many have inferred to be the central role of
national cultures in determining economic
success (Sayer and Walker, 1992). After all,
though it seems somewhat unlikely given the
tenor of commentary in today’s mainstream busi-
ness press, these two models were not all that
long ago much admired by academics and busi-
ness writers alike. Their successes were most
commonly interpreted in terms of national busi-
ness cultures, not only shared by all national
firms, but also deeply engrained in the psyches
and mentalities of workers and the general
public. In retrospect, a lot of this writing strikes
one now as more than a little crude and naive, for
reasons I shall enumerate below.
At the micro scale of the individual firm, the
concept of ‘corporate culture’ came into vogue
in the 1990s as a central variable capable of
explaining both spectacular successes – such as
the rise of Dell and Microsoft – and colossal
failures – the chastening of Xerox, DEC or
Lockheed in the world of big business
(Schoenberger, 1997; 2000). More recently, the
idea has also been invoked to understand the
problems emerging in the wake of highly publi-
cized mergers between corporate giants (for
example, the fundamental incompatibilities
between Daimler and Chrysler, or between
BMW and Rover, only a few years after their
much celebrated unions). The prevailing narra-
tives have laid virtually all the blame upon
incommensurate corporate (and/or national)
cultures that have produced worldviews and
behaviours so fundamentally divergent that they
cannot be overcome.

132 THE CULTURE OF ECONOMY

3029-ch06.qxd 03-10-02 10:40 AM Page 132

Free download pdf