Cultural Geography

(Nora) #1
The knowledge foundations of regional
cultures of production and innovation

As outlined in the previous section, the new
cultural economic geography of production
asserts a clear role for the local – a generally
counterintuitive result in the supposed age of the
global information economy. This idea has
become something of a badge of honour amongst
economic geographers, who now regularly
delight in disabusing their spatially challenged
colleagues in other disciplines of simplistic ideas
about ‘the end of geography’ (O’Brien, 1992),
‘the death of distance’ (Cairncross, 1997) or ‘the
end of the city as we knew it’ (Mitchell, 1995).
Besides the satisfaction of scoring points with
one’s economist friends, it is comforting to be
reassured that ‘geography matters’. Moreover,
the political possibilities associated with this
position defy the stifling determinism of the
‘global economy’ view of the world, in that local
politics are at least open to contestation by local
stakeholders.^6 And yet, just when it appears that
all is right with the world, along comes some
unsettling little complications. It turns out that
the conceptual foundations for arguments pro-
moting the primacy of the local – particularly as
they concern the knowledge and behaviour of the
firm, arguably the principal actor within capitalist
production systems – may not be as solid or
clearly articulated as they should be.
The problems begin with the concept of tacit
knowledge and its relationship to the local. In
much of the recent literature on regional cultures
of production, the distinction between tacit
(‘know how’) and codified (‘know that’) knowl-
edge emerges as central. The touchstone for this
distinction is Michael Polanyi’s oft-quoted
phrase that ‘we can know more than we can tell’
(1966: 4) – alluding to a form of knowledge that
is ‘imperfectly accessible to conscious thought’
(Nelson and Winter, 1982: 79). Underlying this
is a deeper distinction between forms of knowl-
edge (explicit or codified) that can be effectively
expressed and shared using symbolic forms of
representation and other forms of knowledge
(tacit) that defy such representation. Hence, the
tacit component of the knowledge required for
successful performance of a skill defies codifica-
tion or articulation either because the performer
herself is not fully conscious of all the ‘secrets’
of successful performance, or because the codes
of language are not well enough developed or
sufficiently universal to permit explication and
translation.
To show why the concept of tacit knowledge
is so important to the question of local cultures of
production requires a bit of a digression into the

theory of the firm. Recently fashionable theories
of the firm draw their inspiration from the pio-
neering (and long-neglected) work of Edith
Penrose (1959). This approach has been labelled
the competence- or resource-based theory of the
firm because it emphasizes the importance of the
competences, capabilities or resources of indi-
vidual workers and managers within the firm, as
well as the larger collectivity of customs, proce-
dures, routines and practices that define the firm.
It is the collective or social aspect of this capa-
bility which is most interesting, but also the most
difficult to grasp fully when trying to understand
why firms behave the way they do. According to
this view, individuals bring to the firm a set of
attributes and competences based on their formal
education and broader socio-economic back-
ground, as well as their prior work experiences.
But the firm’s capabilities are constituted by
more than the simple sum of its individual
employees’ capabilities. Every firmhas a unique
set of organizational structures, relationships,
rules and routines (explicit and implicit) that help
coordinate the actions of individuals inside the
firm in order to achieve purposive goals – both
the day-to-day objectives entailed in successful
production and the longer-term goals set forth in
a firm’s broader strategy (Kay, 1993).
These features, together with the common
learning experiences of workers within the firm,
also serve as a means for enabling the social pro-
duction and sharing of knowledge, through the
creation of a distinctive ‘knowledge context’ or
framework. As Howells puts it, ‘What indivi-
duals within the firm know and can achieve
depends in part on the nature and characteristics
of the firm’s context’ (2000: 55). Common codes
of communication are essential to this process,
since one of the principal challenges confronting
the firm is how to absorb, share and transform
both codified and tacit knowledge throughout the
organization. In the absence of shared codes
of communication, the transmission of this
knowledge – that is, learning processes within the
firm –will be impeded. Once again quoting from
Howells, who acknowledges the work of
Metcalfe and De Liso (1998):

The tacitness of much knowledge, its indivisibility in
use, the uncertainty of its values in different contexts,
its proprietary nature, and the fact that much of what is
known is jointly produced by the firm’s activities ...
means that the firm provides a central contextual role in
harnessing knowledge to produce new innovative
capabilities. (2000: 56)

Hence we can now see that, according to the
resource- or competence-based view, the
firm’s primary purpose is to absorb, share and

136 THE CULTURE OF ECONOMY

3029-ch06.qxd 03-10-02 10:40 AM Page 136

Free download pdf