Cultural Geography

(Nora) #1
assumed in the new cultural economic geography
literature? Are proximity and face-to-face
contact reallyso important? Isn’t this what the
information technology revolution was supposed
to address?
Good questions all, and the message of Allen,
Amin and others is that we should not presume to
know the answers simply because of the
‘accepted canon’ within the new church. Fair
enough. But before we wax too enthusiastic
about the possibilities of theological revolution,
we need to address two weaknesses in the
critique of the localist position. First, we need to
re-examine the conceptual foundations under-
lying the localist argument. While Allen is
undoubtedly correct in placing the emphasis on
‘thick relationships’ and ‘shared understand-
ings’, pleasantly enigmatic terms like ‘distanci-
ated’ may scan well, but offer us little more than
fleeting insight since they are so open to retrans-
lation and interpretation themselves. Allen’s cri-
tique of the now standard take on tacit
knowledge exposes the fact that its conceptual
foundations are indeed far from solid. Yet, even
with this critique, we still have no clear idea of
the forces and processes stimulating the emer-
gence of thick relationships and shared under-
standings between firms.
Second, it is hard to see how merely asserting
that ‘the local does not really matter’ advances
the state of our understanding in any appreciable
way, so long as statements such as this remain
unsubstantiated empirically. Instead, we need to
get beyond bald assertions to consider the
evidence at hand – something, alas, for which
neither the proponents nor the critics have shown
overwhelming concern, up to this point. In other
words, we need to engage in more ‘learning by
doing’ ourselves since there is apparently still
much hard work to be done, both conceptually
andempirically, to unravel these processes and
relationships more carefully.
Two recent studies by economic geographers –
in sectors as diverse as motor sport engineering
and life insurance – begin to illustrate the true
complexities of knowledge formation and trans-
lation over space. Both of these cases, in their
own way, deepen our understanding of the pre-
cise mechanisms by which local and non-local
processes of knowledge formation intersect at
particular sites of production. In the case of life
insurance, key ‘learning intermediaries’ – each
with their own distinct operative scales – interact
and combine to produce knowledge locally
(French, 2000: 110). When it comes to producing
and applying knowledge in the motor sport
industry, the longitudinal study of top designers’
work histories reveals a great deal about the

geographical structure and channels of knowledge
flows (Henry and Pinch, 2000). At the same
time, spatial propinquity is undeniably important
in creating a discursive dynamics of innovation
as performed through ‘gossip, rumour and obser-
vation’ (2000: 136).
Another helpful source of insight is the new
literature on ‘knowledge management’ emerging
from the business schools and international con-
sulting community. To be sure, this literature is
filled with the typical puffery about ‘harnessing
the organization’s knowledge assets’ to ‘unlock
the firm’s innovative potential’.^10 But when one
strips away all of the marketing hyperbole, one is
confronted with a striking realization: while
large corporations recognize the economic value
of tacit knowledge in producing distinctive com-
petitive advantages, they also know how difficult
it is to transpose and translate it from one local
context to another. Even the ‘success stories’ in
this literature (von Krogh et al., 2000) are not
very convincing, and betray a troubling lack of
sophistication in their understanding of how
‘shared understandings’ develop, or how tacit
knowledge and local cultures are produced
(Gertler, 2001b).^11
Far more enlightening is the recent work of
Brown and Duguid whose intriguing book The
Social Life of Information(2000) tackles these
issues head-on. Brown and Duguid situate their
work very much within the ‘communities of
practice’ approach. However, in contrast to
Wenger and others, they make a key distinction
between this construct and the related idea of
‘networks of practice’ – for example, the 25,000
service reps working worldwide for Xerox
Corporation. Their detailed research of knowl-
edge flows in large organizations leads them to
the following conclusion:

Networks of this sort are notable for their reach – a
reach now extended and fortified by information tech-
nology. Information can travel across vast networks
with great speed and to large numbers but nonetheless
be assimilated in much the same way by whomever
receives it. By contrast, there is relatively little reci-
procity across such networks: that is, network members
don’t interact with one another directly to any signifi-
cant degree. When reach dominates reciprocity like
this, it produces very loosely coupled systems. Collec-
tively, such social systems don’t take action and
produce little knowledge. (2000: 142, emphasis added)

In contrast to this, Brown and Duguid see com-
munities of practice as ‘relatively tight-knit
groups of people who know each other and work
together directly ... face-to-face communities’ in
which reach is limited but ‘reciprocity is strong’
(2000: 143). It is only these small groups that

138 THE CULTURE OF ECONOMY

3029-ch06.qxd 03-10-02 10:40 AM Page 138

Free download pdf