Cultural Geography

(Nora) #1
the hegemony of the west, and to abandon the
myth of development were forged – and perhaps
reached their apogee – in the crucible of what
Perry Anderson calls ‘the neo-liberal grand
slam’ (2000: 15) and the disappearance of the
entire political horizon of the 1960s generation
(2000: 17). His call for ‘renewal’ in terms of
‘accommodation’ and ‘consolidation’ must cast
a long shadow over the prospects for doing
development differently.

ETHNOGRAPHY

At the end of October 2000 I attended a small
seminar organized by the World Bank, the
ground zero of conventional development prac-
tice, on social capital (Woolcock and Narayan,
2000). The meteoric rise and institutionalization
of social capital within the Bank, one of the most
important multilateral regulatory institutions, is
an intriguing issue in itself – and indeed was one
of the topics under discussion. What was it about
this nebulous and rather elastic term, or perhaps
about Robert Putnam (2000) and his social capi-
talist boosters, that provided a language, within a
powerful and complex institution dominated by
economists and engineers, capable of addressing
social relations, poverty and the role of civics?
How, in other words, do we grasp social capital’s
institutionalization – a discursive embedding – in
the World Bank in terms of knowledge, power
and practice? And what on earth might it repre-
sent, if anything, for the way the World Bank
does business? Is it something that the anti-Bank
NGO community might put its collective shoulder
behind? Might the fact that a group of left-
of-center sociologists and economists singing the
praises of social networks, peasant confedera-
tions and decentralized social funds under the
flag of the International Bank for Reconstruction
and Development give the street protestors of
Seattle and Washington DC any reason to
rethink the nature of the beast?
Most of those present felt marginal to the Bank:
economists who had fled in moral apoplexy from
the harsh realities of implementing austerity
measures, and anthropologists soured by the
Bank’s resettlement and indigenous peoples
policies. Among the Bank’s disenfranchised,
social capital had, it turns out, a strategic appeal:
it was a useful way to stimulate debates within
and among the Bank’s divisions and to provide a
ground on which the hegemony of the neoliberal
doctrine might be engaged. It was a discourse,
moreover, with which some economists felt a
degree of intellectual comfort. The workshop

revealed, on the other hand, that in terms of
staffing, resources and legitimacy within the
Bank structure, the social capital group remains
wholly insignificant. The center of gravity within
the institution resides elsewhere, quite specifically
with the unassailable power of the ‘structural
adjustment people’.
Yet the overwhelming sense from the assem-
bled Bank operatives – project managers in
Indonesia, members of the operations and evalu-
ation division, researchers, and one high-ranking
administrator – was that the World Bank was in
some sort of ‘crisis’. On its face this is not exactly
plausible. But at stake in this invocation of crisis
was a series of internally and externally generated
struggles and conflicts best understood in terms
of Gramsci’s notion of ‘moral and intellectual
leadership’. It had, after all, been a rough year for
the world’s major development institution, the
global purveyor of conventional development
wisdom. Not only could large numbers of low-
income countries not afford to borrow from the
World Bank – and a raft of middle-income states
were not interested in borrowing – but the total
Bank lending ($24 billion) was in any case trivial
in relation to private capital flows.
There were various ‘rebellions’ – a term
deployed by a high-ranking Bank official – over
indigenous peoples and biodiversity policies; the
Bank, along with the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) and World Trade Organization
(WTO), has borne the brunt of worldwide popu-
lar protest as the emblem of all that is wrong with
globalization; and to round off the year, there
were two high-visibility resignations. Joseph
Stiglitz, the Vice-President of Research – indis-
putably the voice of theoretical and ideological
leadership in the conventional development
community – resigned, and was then fired at the
behest of US Treasury Secretary Lawrence
Summers. Stiglitz himself referred to the
prospect of being ‘muzzled’, a product of his
frontal assault on US Treasury/IMF adjustment
policies and their handling of the Asian financial
crisis. Several months after Stiglitz’s exposé of
the Bank and the IMF in the New Republic
(2000), Ravi Kanbur, a long-standing Bank
insider who at the time was overseeing the draft-
ing of the World Bank’s flagship text, the World
Development Report 2000 (WDR 2000), on
‘attacking poverty’, also resigned in another bout
of internal warfare (Wade, 2001).
In so far as poverty reduction and its relation
to growth have been a source of substantial
debate and conflict within and outside the Bank
since the 1980s, WDR 2000 – a bellwether and
reference point for future development policy –
was naturally going to be passionately debated.

ALTERNATIVE MODERN 443

3029-ch23.qxd 03-10-02 4:55 PM Page 443

Free download pdf