Cultural Geography

(Nora) #1
there is a sort of ineluctable logic that has led
from the posing of development as a form of
modernity to the recognition that in a world of
globalization and a global development industry,
what is at stake is the making of alternative
modernities. But to make such a claim is on
its face far removed from some of the post-
development work. To think of alternative moderni-
ties is to admit modernity is inescapable and, as
Gaonkar (2001: 1) says, to desist from specula-
tions of its end. In the same way, when Diouf
(2000) says that the cosmopolitanism of the rural
Senegalese Mourides traders who now operate
sophisticated global economic networks in
Turin, Paris and New York is not simply
informed by the western trajectory of modernity
alone, he has done nothing but affirm the powers
of non-western capitalistaccumulation (indeed
his article reads like African nationalism meeting
the chamber of commerce!). All of which is to
say that the powers of capitalist modernity are
undiminished. Could not Diouf be read as a vari-
ant of Weber’s Protestant ethic (‘the Muslim
ethic and the rise of capitalism’)?
Chakrabarty at the end of his ‘postcolonial’
Provincializing Europe(2000) says his task has
been to create conjoined and disjunctive
genealogies for European categories of political
modernity, to keep in tension the necessary dia-
logue between the universal history of capital
(‘History I’) and the diverse ways of being
human (‘History II’). But what exactly has this
distinction yielded as regards the prospects for
the on-the-ground hegemony of development
practice? Not much, I fear. In the same way
Gibson-Graham and Ruccio (2001), in a critical
‘poststructural’ rereading of my own work, des-
perately search for some spheres in which
non-capitalism resides untouched by the over-
whelming powers of capitalism (as they interpret
my analysis). Whether their reading is right or
wrong – I would say for the record that certain
threads of Marxism have always been concerned
with diversity and the spaces opened within
capitalism for non-capitalist production, and
their interpretation of my Marxism is totally
wrong-headed – matters less than the fact that
they do not to seek to abandon progress and
development but rather try to understand the pos-
sibilities for non-exploitative and fair forms of
produced wealth, which sounds like most of left-
of-center conventional development theory.
It is also striking that the cultural creativity
and the ‘creative adaptation’ (Gaonkar, 2001)
that are emphasized in this work bear the hall-
mark of great familiarity. In Gibson-Graham and
Ruccio’s reading of my Gambia work, the
women’s work gangs and the struggles over the

conjugal contract are (cultural specificity
notwithstanding) very familiar stories. After
reading Chakrabarty’s account of Calcutta, it is
not the sense of hybridity or the difference that
remains, but the extraordinary resonances with
Marshall Berman’s account of (western) modern-
ity. One wonders whether the renarrativizing and
the hybridities and the cosmopolitan capitalisms
can really substantiate a claim that the ‘not-
quite-modern’ disrupts the complacent march of
progress (Gupta, 1998: 233) or unsettles ‘the
representational efficacy of the relations of global
inequality’ (1998: 231).
In some quarters, then, the cultural geography
of development has, along with much post-
colonial and poststructural theory, come to reluc-
tantly admit the universality of capitalist
modernity. There is, it must be said, an obvious
tension between those who stand at a critical
angle to western Enlightenment and who trumpet
grassroots postmodernism, and those who in
acknowledging the inescapability of the modern
invoke a multiplicity of other modernities. In the
former there is a danger of the worst of populist
myopia. In the latter there is the vain hope that in
the renarrativization of western hegemony (the
discovery of alternative modernities) resides a
sort of civilizational parity. Both tend to occlude
the terrible realities of unprecedented global
economic inequality and the crude violence of
twenty-first-century empire. A 1950s modern-
ization theorist might well offer a wry smile.

NOTES

1 The point being that 50 years of the development busi-
ness has witnessed very little in terms of the radical
improvement of poverty and material circumstances of
the poor, and that development has little to offer in the
face of growing economic inequality and ecological mis-
ery. Obviously a long line of radical Marxist develop-
ment theory preceded this critical turn in the 1980s,
stretching back to Marx himself, to the early theorists of
imperialism (Lenin, Luxemburg, Trotsky) and their
twentieth-century followers (Bill Warren) and subse-
quently to Third World theorists of underdevelopment
(the Latin American dependistas, the French Marxists
such as Claude Meillassoux and Pierre-Philippe Rey, the
Indian mode of production debates, and the grand theory
of Samir Amin). For a review see Richard Peet (2000).
2 ‘It looks as if economic growth may not merely fail to
solve social and political difficulties; certain types of
economic growth may actually cause them’ (Seers, 1969).
3 In this chapter I have not referred to the relevant work
on feminism that is covered by McEwan in Chapter 21.
4 In his new book Seeing Like a State(1998), James
Scott provides a complementary critique, seeing in
‘high modernism’ the desire to link the high ideals of

ALTERNATIVE MODERN 449

3029-ch23.qxd 03-10-02 4:55 PM Page 449

Free download pdf