Perfect Competition versus Pure Monopoly 333
the lower average-cost-based price spurs a significant increase in output and,
therefore, in welfare.
However, average-cost pricing does not exhaust the opportunities for wel-
fare gains. At output QR8, the demand curve still lies above marginal cost;
that is, MB MC. Output should be expanded and price lowered. In fact, opti-
mal price and output can be determined by the intersection of the demand
and marginal cost curves. This outcome is referred to as marginal-cost pricing
because it fulfills the efficiency condition P MB MC. Consumers are
encouraged to purchase more output as long as their value exceeds the (low)
marginal cost of production.
If marginal-cost pricing is efficient, why isn’t it universally used? The prac-
tical difficulty with this pricing scheme should be evident. Price falls short of
the firm’s declining average cost P MC AC—so the firm makes persist-
ent losses. One way to maintain P MC while making good this loss is to have
FIGURE 8.4
A Natural Monopoly
Regulators seek to
implement average-
cost pricing where the
demand curve
intersects the AC curve.
PM = 6
Q
Electricity (Kilowatt-Hours)
Dollars per Unit of Output
Electricity
demand
PR = 3
Monopoly outcome:
PM = $6, QM = 5
Declining
average
cost
10
MC
9
8
7
5
4
MC = 1
2
11
0 123456789
Average-cost
pricing under
regulation
10 11
Marginal
revenue
$12
12
c08Monopoly.qxd 9/29/11 1:31 PM Page 333