Market Failure Due to Externalities 457
form the new curve, MTC (marginal total cost). The original supply curve
embodies the internalcost of producing the chemical, that is, those borne by
producers. This marginal cost is simply $4 per liter. However, the true, full cost
of producing the chemical is the sum of all costs per unit, internal and external.
Thus, the full cost of expanding output comes to MIC MEC $4 $1 $5.
In the figure, this is shown by the curve MTC.
Once the externality is recognized, we can pinpoint the industry’s effi-
cient level of output using the logic of marginal benefits and costs. Optimal
industry output occurs at the intersection of the demand curve and the “full’’
supply curve, at output level Q* 8 million liters. Here, the marginal bene-
fit from the last unit consumed exactly matches the full (internal plus exter-
nal) marginal cost of producing this unit.^6 The efficient level of output is
lower than the competitive outcome, Qc10 million liters. By failing to rec-
ognize the externality, the competitive market produces too much output
and associated pollution, relative to the efficient outcome. Figure 11.1 also
shows the deadweight loss from the excess production, QcQ*—the trian-
gular shaded area where marginal benefits to consumers fall below the full
marginal costs of supply.
The inefficiency problems associated with externalities are caused by
incorrect pricing. The competitive price of $4 reflects only the marginal
internal costs of the chemical. But the full marginal cost is higher by the
amount of the marginal external cost (here, $1). In the figure, the efficient
price is actually $5, where P* MB MTC. This simple observation sug-
gests a direct way for a government regulator to implement the efficient
outcome:
An efficient means of regulation is to tax the producer of a negative externality an
amount exactly equal to the associated marginal external cost.
In the chemical example, the external cost of pollution is $1 (per extra
cubic foot of pollutant), so this is the appropriate tax. In other words, each
chemical firm pays a tax, T $1, for each cubic foot of pollution it dis-
charges. What is the effect of this tax on the typical chemical producer? By
continuing to produce the chemical with pollution as a by-product, the firm
incurs an out-of-pocket cost (per additional unit of output) equal to MIC
T MIC MEC. Since the tax is set exactly equal to the marginal external
cost (MEC), the producer of the externality is made to pay its true social
cost. In this way, setting the right tax (T MEC) serves to “internalize the exter-
nality.” With the tax in place, the relevant industry supply curve is MTC (up
(^6) For the interested students, the figure’s demand curve is given by MB 9 .5Q. The competi-
tive equilibrium, Pc$4 and Qc10 million, is found by setting MB MIC. The efficient level
of output, P $5 and Q 8 million, satisfies MB MIC MEC.
c11RegulationPublicGoodsandBenefitCostAnalysis.qxd 9/29/11 1:34 PM Page 457