9781118041581

(Nancy Kaufman) #1
Organizational Design 605

arrangement raise the incentive to supply extra effort? The answer is yes. As
shown in item 4 of Table 14.3b, the worker maximizes his or her profit (salary
less disutility) by choosing a mediumlevel of effort. The incentive contract has
induced additional effort and has increased the total profit pie. Nevertheless,
the worker still does not have sufficient incentive to adopt optimal behavior,
that is, exert high effort. (Under high effort, the worker’s expected compen-
sation is (.5)(85,000) 10,000 $52,500. Thus, the worker’s net profit is
52,500 45,000 $7,500, or $1,000 less than the medium-effort outcome.)
As this example shows, raising the worker’s profit share is the key to induc-
ing extra effort. In fact, allowing the worker to keep 100 percent of his or her con-
tribution to profit ensures an optimal choice of effort. Now the worker’s interest
is identical to the overall objective of profit maximization. Taking full account of
the extra benefits and costs (disutility) of additional effort, the worker adopts
optimal behavior. Unfortunately, even this solution has problems. First, 100 per-
cent profit participation represents a very risky contract for the worker. After all,
the gross profit outcome in Table 14.3 will be either $100,000 or $50,000. That’s
a significant risk. Any risk-averse worker will demand a premium for bearing this
risk. To put this another way, besides the disutility of effort, the personal “cost”
to the worker associated with risk bearing could well be on the order of $5,000
or more. Thus, imposing this risk on the worker shrinks the total pie by this
amount. Second, under the terms of the contract, the worker guarantees the
employer a profit of $25,000. Because the employer has a guaranteed profit, the
employer’s incentives are negligible. But typically, the employer’s actions and
efforts will contribute to the worker’s ultimate output. Now the proverbial moral
hazard shoe is on the other foot. Will the employer adopt optimal behavior?
Absent incentives, the answer is problematic.
In the interest of realism, we can generalize this stylized example and
extend it in a number of directions. (The appendix to this chapter presents
just such an extended model.) Whatever the specific model, the degree of con-
tractual incentives remains the key issue. Suppose that (1) the worker’s output
depends mainly on effort (and only partly on factors beyond his or her con-
trol); and (2) his or her choice of effort has a large impact on profit. Both of
these factors argue for high-powered incentives (i.e., high profit-sharing rates).
As in the preceding example, profit sharing induces greater worker effort, mit-
igating (though not eliminating) the moral hazard problem.

Should a firm sell its product in its own stores or instead by contracting with
a franchisee? As we noted in Chapter 2, the franchise arrangement embodies
high-powered incentives for the franchisee; the franchise manager’s effort
and choices directly influence the franchise’s profits. By contrast, under an
employment relationship, the employee typically faces low-powered incen-
tives; typically the employee has limited managerial discretion and little (or
zero) profit sharing.

Integration or
Franchising?

c14AsymmetricInformationandOrganizationalDesign.qxd 9/26/11 11:03 AM Page 605

Free download pdf