9781118041581

(Nancy Kaufman) #1
may be well below his reported bid. In short, he should report his true
value so that the auction house can bid on his behalf (exactly as he
would himself if he were present at the auction).


  1. a. Against a single rival, the optimal bid is $2.4 million implying an
    expected profit of (2.9 2.4)(.4) $.2 million. Against two rivals,
    the optimal bid is $2.6 million implying an expected profit of
    (2.9 2.6)(.6)^2 $.108 million.
    b. Each firm’s equilibrium bidding strategy is
    .


Thus, the optimal bid is (1/3)(2) (2/3)(2.9) $2.6 million.


  1. a. A firm can only lose money by bidding above its value. Bidding below
    one’s value risks getting neither position and can only help if moving
    down to position two is more profitable than winning the top
    position. Firm 1’s profit from winning the top position is: (50–35)(5) 
    75¢ per minute. If it were to bid just below 35¢, it would win the
    second position at a price of 30¢, implying a profit of: (50–30)(3) 
    60¢ per minute. Neither firm 1 nor any other firm has a reason to bid
    below value. Therefore, bidding one’s true value is an equilibrium.
    b. Now if firm 1 bids just below 35¢ and wins the second position at 20¢,
    its profit is: (50–20)(3) 90¢ per minute (greater than its profit from
    bidding truthfully and winning the top position). Truthful bidding is
    no longer optimal.

  2. a. Under blind bidding, each firm’s reservation price is simply the
    expected value of the film. The common expected value for each
    bidder is (1/3)(10,000) (1/3)(6,000) (1/3)(2,000) $6,000,
    and this will be the equilibrium bid for each in a sealed-bid auction.
    Thus, the distributor’s revenue from the auction will exactly equal the
    expected value of the film. If the distributor delays the bidding until
    the uncertainty is resolved, exhibitors will bid the full (certain) value
    of the film. Again the expected revenue is $6,000. However, if
    exhibitors are risk averse, their reservation values (and, therefore,
    bids) will be below the film’s expected value under blind bidding.
    Bids for previewed films will be unaffected (since these films carry no
    risk). With risk-averse bidders the exhibitor increases its expected
    revenue by previewing the films.
    b. Selective screening works only if bidders are naive. Sophisticated
    bidders will anticipate that unscreened films are likely to have lower
    expected box-office receipts than the rest of the films. They will bid
    accordingly.
    c. Against an astute bidder, the less well-informed theaters must bid
    cautiously to avoid the winner’s curse, that is, winning films that the
    astute bidder knows are poor box-office bets. This kind of bid


bi(1/3)(2)(2/3)vi

32 Answers to Odd-Numbered Problems

BMAns.qxd 9/26/11 11:18 AM Page 32

Free download pdf