Buddhism in India

(sharon) #1
Buddhist Civilisation 143

dysfunctional because their fatalism rejects all attempts to alter that
society and holds out no hope for changing the human condition.
Buddhism, on the other hand, fits the needs of the new society and
provides a solution to its dilemmas: it projects the sorrows of class
exploitation, but in interpreting them idealistically, it gives only the
illusion of a solution and so reconciles people to their class position.
In this sense, it is an ‘opium of the people’ serving the interests of
the elite.
Kosambi’s interpretation is more nuanced. Chattopadhyaya does
not go into the difference between Buddhism and Brahmanism in
terms of social function. Kosambi does. He describes the increasing
irrelevance of the Vedic sacrifice to the needs of the new social
order, and the needless expenses the sacrifice entails. Buddhist non-
violence is seen as providing the final blow to the religion which
endorsed sacrifices, and as serving the interests of the rising states
in minimising the expenses of violence. For Kosambi, Buddhism is
ultimately a pacifistic religion useful to rulers. His explanation of
the triumph of Brahmanism is basically that it proved capable of
taking over from Buddhism this major achievement: it adopted
non-violence partially. Once Buddhism accomplished what had
been historically necessary, it became less relevant, and its increasing
decadence—as reflected in the wealth tied up in the monasteries
and the presumed alienation of the Sangha from the ordinary
believer—made it positively harmful. Brahmanism, in contrast,
could take over and foster a bhakti devotionalism that suited the
needs of a feudal society. Brahmans also could maintain their role
in society by pioneering the transformation of a forest-based economy
into agriculture-based economy and by absorbing hunting and
gathering tribes into a caste-based agricultural society. Though he
does not use the term, Kosambi at points comes close to viewing
Brahmanism as the ‘national religion’ of India, capable of providing
what is necessary for economic growth and capable of reform.
One important question arises from most Marxist interpretations.
Kosambi, for example, defines history as the study of the succession
of the modes of production. In the classic Marxist theory, these
stages are primitive communism slavery, feudalism and capitalism
(and then, of course, socialism). Buddhism in these terms was, for
both Kosambi and Chattopadhyaya, presumably an ideal religion
for the age of slavery. Yet it is never shown what about it is
characteristic of a slave society. Indeed, the society of the first

was related to issues of technology and production. In one rather
interesting Jataka known as the ‘Great Tunnel Jataka’ (#546), the
Bodhisattva is a teacher-advisor known as Mahosadha who can be
called an engineer: he constructs huge buildings and gardens; he
builds great ramparts with moats, reservoirs, storehouses for the
king, and he constructs a huge tunnel with ‘hundreds of lamp-cells,
also fitted with machinery, so that when one was opened all
opened, and when one was shut, all were shut.’ Mahosadha is the
son of a ‘rich man’ who is sometimes described as a merchant, but
he is called a ‘clodhopper’ and a ‘farmer’s son’ by his enemies, and
he marries a woman whose father is a merchant who has fallen on
bad days and makes his living ploughing the land. Mahosadha’s
own demonstrated ability at architecture and engineering shows a
‘hands on’ approach of this ‘commoner’ birth.


Religion and Economic Development


Now we are in a position where we can take up one of the most
important and controversial issues regarding religion and society—
the link between religion and economic development. Here the
most important contributions are those of Marx and Weber.
The Marxist view the relationship between religion and society
essentially in terms of a one-way causality. Religion, whether
described as the ‘opium of the people’ binding them to an exploitative
society or as the ‘sigh of the oppressed’ expressing their anguish
at exploitation, is seen as part of the ideological superstructure,
produced by and reflecting socio-economic structures but having
no independent causal influence on them. Thus Marxists have
generally viewed Buddhism as simply one of many ways of reflect-
ing social-economic relations, expressing in this case the needs of a
developing, agricultural-urban, surplus-producing and commercially-
oriented society, but not contributing much to it.
Two major expressions of this perspective in India are the
works of Debiprasad Chattopadhyay and D.D. Kosambi.
Chattopadhyaya’s interpretation, which we have cited in Chapter 1,
is quite simple. His major work analyses the Lokayata tradition and
sees in it the reflection of the dying communal tribal order and its
remnants. In contrast, the other samana traditions express the
misery and exploitation of the rising class society, but are socially


142 Buddhism in India

Free download pdf