The Economist - USA (2019-07-13)

(Antfer) #1

54 Britain The EconomistJuly 13th 2019


2 power in 2010 on a promise to balance the
fiscal books, have long been tough on bene-
fits. In a conference speech in 1992 Peter
Lilley, then the welfare secretary, adapted
the libretto of a Gilbert and Sullivan musi-
cal: “I’ve got a little list / Of benefit offend-
ers who I’ll soon be rooting out / And who
never would be missed.” Yet even by Con-
servative standards, cuts to working-age
welfare under Mr Osborne were severe. In
the 2010-15 parliament about £30bn (equiv-
alent to over 1% of gdp) was stripped away;
single parents in work lost benefits worth
6% of their after-tax income. Reforms an-
nounced shortly after the general election
in 2015 fell even harder on the poor.
The highly visible effects of these poli-
cies, from a proliferation of food banks to a
rise in rough sleeping, have convinced
many people that Mr Osborne went too far.
As on many subjects, public opinion on
welfare tends to be “thermostatic”, says
Ben Baumberg Geiger of the University of
Kent. Once policies become harsher or
softer than the level preferred by the pub-
lic, voters send a signal and the govern-
ment adjusts the policy “temperature” ac-
cordingly. Philip Hammond, who replaced
Mr Osborne in 2016, has slightly increased
the working-age welfare budget.
Changes in other policy areas may help
to explain why the public has gone softer
on welfare. The growing concern in the
2000s with benefit fraud and abuse coin-
cided with a big rise in immigration, espe-
cially after 2004, when residents of eight
eastern European countries got the right to
work in Britain. Voters feared the prospect
of migrants coming to live off the taxpayer
(many did indeed claim in-work benefits,
though very few lived off the dole). A sense
that Brexit will lead to lower immigration
may have convinced people that there is no
longer such a risk involved in having a gen-
erous welfare policy. Once the government
is seen to be acting on a topic, public opin-
ion moves on, says Andrew Cooper, a poll-
ster at Populus.
The change in mood is matched in the
political debate. Not long ago, opposition
parties boasted that they would be tougher
on welfare than the incumbent. As recently
as 2015 Labour—then under the caretaker
leadership of Harriet Harman, a veteran of
Mr Blair’s administrations—whipped its
mps to abstain on a vote on Mr Osborne’s
benefit cuts, rather than vote against them.
Ed Miliband, who preceded her as leader,
promised to crack down on migrants re-
ceiving benefits.
A bunch of left-wing backbenchers, in-
cluding Jeremy Corbyn and John McDon-
nell, ignored Ms Harman’s orders, with Mr
McDonnell pledging to “swim through vo-
mit” to oppose the cuts. Mr Corbyn has
since become Labour’s leader, and the party
has moved in a different direction. It has
mooted a universal basic income and hint-

edthatitwouldscrapuniversalcredit.La-
bour’semollientapproachmeansthatthe
Toriesnolongerneedtobemachoabout
welfare. “Politicians now in Parliament
can’tgetupandspeakthewaytheydida
fewyearsago,”saysMrMcDonnell,now
theshadowchancellor.“Inthosedays,we
werestillat‘scrounger’andalltherest.”
Oneperson,atleast,hasnotchanged
hismindonbenefits.WhenaskedlastOc-
toberwhetherheregrettedhisactionsin
government,MrOsborneadmittedtopoli-
cyfailuresregardingtheeu, immigration
andthebankingindustry.Buthemounted
a staunchdefenceofhiswelfarecuts.“If
youaregoingtohavetodealwiththefact
thecountry was spending toomuch, it
wouldbeabitoddtoleaveoutthevery
largechunkthegovernmentwasspending
onwelfare,”said MrOsborne. Voters,it
seems,nowdisagree. 7

E


arlier this year minicab drivers
turned up to protest outside the offices
of Transport for London (tfl). “Sadiq Khan,
shame on you!” they chanted. “Not the
drivers, not the poor, tax the operators
more!” The cause of their ire? The mayor’s
decision that minicab drivers, including
those who use Uber, should join the gen-
eral public in paying £11.50 ($14.30) a day to
drive in the centre of the capital. “We hoped
the public-pressure route would work,” ex-
plains Jason Moyer-Lee of the iwgbunion,
which organised the protest. But Mr Khan
stood firm—so the union has decided to try
the legal route.
On July 10th the High Court began to
hear its case that the introduction of the
charge for minicab drivers is racially dis-
criminatory and breaks the European Con-
vention on Human Rights. As a public
body, tflmust obey the Equality Act by
avoiding indirect discrimination, which
happens when a seemingly neutral rule has
a disproportionate impact on a protected
group. An example could be a rule making
all employees work full-time, which would
disproportionately affect women, who are
more likely than men to be carers.
Since the rules changed in April, the
congestion-charge exemption has been
available only to black cabs and to the 0.6%
of private-hire vehicles that are accessible
to wheelchairs. This is where the iwgbsays
the indirect discrimination comes in. Al-
though Uber drivers and cabbies perform

similar roles, shuttling Londoners about
the city, they are very different people. Ac-
cording to a recent survey, only 8% of mini-
cab drivers are white-British, compared
with 80% of black-cab drivers.
Black-cab drivers have little sympathy
for their rivals. The number of private-hire
drivers in the city has almost doubled since
Uber arrived in 2012. “There’s too many of
them on the road. Something needs to be
done,” complains Miles, as he chomps on a
sandwich outside a small green hut,
known as a cabmen’s shelter, on the Em-
bankment. The congestion charge was ex-
tended to cover minicabs to do just that.
Research carried out on behalf of tflpre-
dicts that it will cut private-hire traffic by
6%, but overall traffic by just 1%.
Indirect discrimination is permissible
if it is a “proportionate means” to achieve a
“legitimate aim”. It is, for example, fair to
make trainee firefighters pass a fitness test
before they jump into burning buildings,
even though such a test discriminates
against old people. But the iwgbargues
that there are other ways to achieve the le-
gitimate aim of reducing traffic—such as
raising the congestion charge for all driv-
ers—and that a fall in the supply of mini-
cabs may harm people with disabilities
who do not need a wheelchair.
tflresponds that the most price-sensi-
tive traffic has already been priced out of
the city, so a rise in the congestion charge
for all would make little difference. Taxi
drivers will hope it is a winning argument.
In exchange for learning the Knowledge, a
gruelling feat requiring them to remember
25,000 roads and 100,000 landmarks, they
earn perks such as the right to pick people
up off the street (whereas minicabs must
be booked) and to drive in bus lanes. If
minicab drivers have their way, the incen-
tive to spend all those hours memorising
road names will be a little less strong. 7

Is the congestion charge racially
discriminatory?

London taxis

The Courts of


Justice, please


Black cab, white driver
Free download pdf