152 Optimizing Optimization
estimated expectile at the end of the sample period, μˆT. From the previous
discussion, we know that it satisfies:
μˆ,TT ˆ ,ˆ
[()]()Ωλμ λμλDR DR R
1
where the subscript on the inverse matrix indicates the T -th row. Recall that
each diagonal element of DR()λμ, can only take on two values, ω and 1 ω.
As a result, on any set Λ R n such that DRˆ()λ is constant ∀ λ Λ , the objec-
tive function is linear in λ. De Rossi (2009) shows that the objective function
μωˆ;T 1 (( ) )yλ , viewed as a function of λ * , is piecewise linear and convex. This
implies that the solution to the maximization problem must be on a vertex. The
simplex algorithm starts from an arbitrary vertex and moves along the edges
of the “ surface ” until it reaches the maximum. At each step, the ω -expectiles
of the portfolios corresponding to the new vertices are estimated and used for
prediction one step ahead. The absence of local minima makes the optimiza-
tion procedure robust and reliable.
It is straightforward to see that the procedure can be used to deal with
objective functions that include alpha terms. Call α a vector of expected asset
returns. We can impose the additional inequality constraint λαr , where r
is a preassigned constant. The asset allocation procedure would then minimize
risk subject to an expected return of at least r.
The parameters q and ω are inputs to the asset allocation procedure. How
should a portfolio manager choose their values?
First , q can be estimated from the data as argued above, e.g., from a time
series of returns to the minimum variance portfolio. The parameter can be
viewed as a signal to noise ratio: The higher q , the more information content
can be found in the observations. In addition, q is related to turnover. The
more responsive the model is to changes in expectiles over time, the larger
the amount of trading. By looking at historical data, the value of q can be
fine-tuned to match the desired turnover level.
As for the parameter ω , Manganelli (2007) highlights the fact that the
maximum expectile objective can be interpreted in a utility maximization
framework. Minimizing the EVaR is equivalent to maximizing:
EU Y((μ ))
where Y is the portfolio return and
Ux
xx
μ xx
μ
μ
ω
ω
μμ
()
if
()if
1
<
⎧
⎨
⎪⎪
⎪
⎩
⎪⎪
⎪
If we interpret U(x) as a utility function, then it is easy to see that as ω → 0.5,
the preferences approach risk neutrality: all the investor cares about is the
expected return (which is the 50% expectile). For ω 0.5, however, lower lev-
els of ω correspond to higher risk aversion.