The Times - UK (2022-05-17)

(Antfer) #1
the times | Tuesday May 17 2022 37

Business


Haldane let the inflation cat out of


the bag, and warned it was a tiger


Like the priestess
Cassandra, Andy
Haldane was ignored

F


or close watchers of “de-
globalisation”, India’s
decision at the weekend to
ban all wheat exports
marked another watershed
for the world’s creaking trading
system. The world’s second largest
wheat producer announced an
immediate ban on overseas sales
grain in an attempt to contain
domestic prices in the name of food
security. The decision was a volte-
face by Delhi’s nationalist
government, which days earlier had
promised it would “feed the world”
by ramping up wheat production and
gaining market share in the wake of
supply disruptions from Russia and
Ukraine.
India’s move is the latest in a wave
of global food protectionism that
risks tipping the world’s poorest
people further into starvation and

fanning the flames of inflation in the
rich world. More than 35 countries
have imposed restrictions on grain
imports since the war in Ukraine,
according to the World Bank,
crackdowns prompted by a record
increases in global grain and
cooking oil prices since Russia’s
invasion in late February. As the
collective breadbasket of the world,
Russia and Ukraine account for a
quarter of the world’s wheat exports,
two thirds of sunflower oil and a
quarter of barley exports.
Wheat export prices hit a 14-year
year high in March. Maize, one of
the world’s three staple grains with
wheat and rice, is trading at its
highest level since records began.
Global food prices rose by 34 per
cent last month, according to the
United Nations’ Food and
Agriculture Organisation.
Rather than capitalising on record
prices, producers such as India are
choosing to batten down the hatches
and retreat into protectionism to
feed their own people first. Delhi’s
decision comes after Indonesia
announced a ban last month on all

exports of palm oil, the most-used
vegetable oil in the world used in
foods and goods such as shampoo
and is difficult to substitute.
Poorer countries are uniquely
exposed to the political and social
ramifications of spiralling food costs.
Lower-income populations spend
disproportionately high amounts of
their incomes on basic goods.
Indonesia’s government was
prompted into action by domestic
palm oil shortages, surging inflation
and the upcoming Eid feast in the
world’s most populous Muslim
country. India’s government said its
decision had been prompted by
rising inflation and bad weather
affecting harvests.
Yet the nature of the world’s food
system means that trade restrictions
anywhere invariably drive prices
higher for the many. India is
especially vulnerable to changes in
global food prices, which account for
45 per cent of its domestic inflation
basket. South Asia as a whole runs
the world’s biggest food trade deficit.
Food protectionism is a beggar-
thy-neighbour policy. For all the
superficial attraction of food
autarky, trade embargoes push
prices higher across related
commodity markets, forcing other
countries into tit-for-tat retaliation
to protect their domestic supply.
The world has been here before,
notably during the food crisis of
2008-11, the consequences of which
included sparking mass protests
during the Arab Spring. But, as
noted by the International Panel of
Experts on Sustainable Food
Systems, fragilities in the world food
system have not been addressed.
Chief among them is the fact that
populous regions such as sub-
Saharan Africa are reliant on a
handful of vital crops from a limited
number of foreign suppliers. In good
times, global supply chains function
well and can bring down prices;
when disruption hits, the poorest
suffer the most.
The tragic irony of today’s turmoil
is that the world is not in the grip of
a food shortage but a waste crisis.
One third of all food produced is lost
or wasted every year. Using only a
fifth of this waste could feed almost
900 million people, according to
Friends of the Earth.

Mehreen Khan


It is 15 months since
Andy Haldane, who
was chief economist
at the Bank of
England, gave what
has turned out to be one of the most
prescient speeches in the history of
British economics. And no one
heeded a word of it.
In it, he tentatively warned that
inflation could be much greater than
expected as the economy recovered
from Covid. He was concerned that
central banks were being too
complacent, that the inflation “tiger”
was being let out of the cage and
would be hard to tame.
The UK inflation rate at the time
was a mere 0.7 per cent, well below
the 2 per cent target. Like Cassandra,
Haldane was destined not to be
believed — at least not by his eight
fellow interest rate-setters on the
Bank’s monetary policy committee.
The base rate was then left
unchanged at its 300-year low of
0.1 per cent for another ten months.
The Bank was to carry on with its
£875 billion money creation and
bond-buying spree, a programme
known as quantitative easing, for
another 13 months and it still hasn’t
started to reverse it.
And Andrew Bailey, the governor,
was to persist for many more months
with his sunny claim that inflation
would be mild and transitory and that
the super-stimulative position of the
Bank was the correct one.
Inflation today is 7 per cent, is
expected to rise to 9.1 per cent when
the official number for April is
declared tomorrow and, according to
the Bank’s own forecasts, is set to hit
more than 10 per cent by the end of
the year, five times higher than target.
A tiger, indeed.
Of course, much of this has been
due to recent external shocks, as
Bailey was anxious to explain
to MPs yesterday. There
was “not a lot we can
do about 80 per cent
of it [the current
inflation burst]”, he
claimed, citing the
hit to energy
costs caused by
the Ukraine
conflict and the
new shutdowns in

China. All the more reason, his critics
argue, why he should have tightened
earlier, when he had the chance, to
bear down on domestic pressures, in
particular a red-hot labour market, to
put downward pressure on other
prices that he could control and to re-
anchor inflation expectations.
This was never about seriously
putting on the brakes on the economy.
It was just about pulling back from the
Bank’s full-throttle setting, inching
back towards a more normal monetary
policy stance while the opportunity
was there. Which is why Bailey’s
claims about “carefully calibrated
policy” sound so hollow to some.
If MPs are right to question
whether he was “asleep at the wheel”
last year, then large chunks of the
City and the economics profession
have questions to answer, too. Apart
from Sir Howard Davies, chairman of
NatWest, who called for a rate rise in
July, it is hard to think of one senior
figure from the private sector who
went public to call for tighter policy.
Behind closed doors, there were
sceptics, but no one wanted to call for
something as unpopular as a rise in
the cost of mortgages. Even fewer in
the City were publicly demanding a
reversal of QE, which was gratifyingly
puffing up asset values and therefore
their end-of-year bonuses.
Some economists did a bit better.
From June onwards, our own Times
Shadow MPC, an informal grouping
of economics grandees, began calling
for QE to be wound down. By July
the House of Lords’ economic affairs
committee, whose members included
Lord King of Lothbury, the former
Bank governor, also were worried,
publishing their report QE: A
Dangerous Addiction? However, most
economists last year seemed perfectly
content to buy the “transient” theory.
Why were Haldane’s concerns
ignored? First, because he
was using his
imagination, not a skill
approved of by a
profession much
happier seizing on
trends and
cautiously
extrapolating
them another
quarter into the
future. What,
argued Haldane, if
things were now
different? What if the
globalisation and

demographic trends of the past few
decades, which had been so potent in
keeping a lid on prices, were going
into reverse? What if the slow
recovery after the financial crisis in
2008 was not a useful template for
recovery after Covid? What if money
supply growth (then running at 20 per
cent) started to behave in a different
way, pushing up spending growth and
prices? What if the nation actually
went out and spent the hundreds of
billions of pounds of savings built up
during lockdown? That approach
required a leap of faith. Much safer to
stick with the herd and wait for hard,
unambiguous facts, even if by then it
might be too late.
A second reason for economics to
be slow to adjust to this new era has
been an understandable reluctance to
generalise from particulars. Yes, there
were individual bottlenecks — in
everything from computer chips to
carbon dioxide. Yes, some
occupations were bagging gigantic
pay rises, from lawyers to lorry
drivers. But it was tempting to play
down what could just turn out to be
confusing noise and focus on the
macro picture. The backward-looking
official data weren’t producing such
egregious danger signals. Much more
scientific to concentrate on the dry
data from the ONS than listen to
anecdotal (and therefore suspect)
evidence from business leaders
howling about wage pressures,
unfilled vacancies and skill shortages.
Third, and more controversially, the
Bank might not be as independent
from its political masters as it would
like to think. QE, say the critics, is a
cynical exercise in deficit funding,
helping the Treasury to borrow on
the cheap. A prolonged burst of
inflation will do wonders in eroding
government debt in real terms.
Bailey has form in trying to please
ministers. While heading the
Financial Conduct Authority, he took
charge of an ill-conceived crusade to
water down City listing rules to allow
Saudi Aramco to gain a premium
listing in London. It was a pet goal of
Theresa May, the prime minister.
Aramco never came. Whatever the
explanation, the
tiger is uncaged and
untamed and
unquestionably
here.

‘‘


’’


Patrick Hosking is Financial Editor
of The Times

Mehreen Khan is Economics Editor of
The Times

Food protectionism risks


inflation for the rich and


starvation for the poor


Wheat price
$14

12

10

8

6
Jul Sep Nov Jan Mar May

Source: tradingeconomics.com

(Per bushel)

Patrick Hosking


d

to explain
There
an
nt

ignored? Firs
was using
imagin
appro
pro
ha
tr
ca
e
th
qu
fut
arg
thin
dddiffere
globalis
Free download pdf