The Washington Post - USA (2022-05-29)

(Antfer) #1
SUNDAY, MAY 29 , 2022. THE WASHINGTON POST EZ BD B5

standing of the dynamics of inequality in the
21st-century economy.
Bernanke’s problem, like that of many of his
Fed colleagues past and present, is a refusal to
acknowledge the prevalence of asset bubbles,
the extent of their impact on the economy and
the Fed’s role in creating them, both through
expansionary monetary policy and weak fi-
nancial regulation. It was this blind spot about
the irrationality and games-playing on Wall
Street that led Bernanke to assure the country
in 2008 that the subprime mortgage market
was simply too small to threaten the banking
system. And it is the same blind spot that
allowed the Fed in recent years to dismiss the
meme stocks, the tech unicorns and the crypto
insanity, along with the explosion of private
credit, and characterize it as nothing more
than one of those occasional exuberances
unworthy of a policy response. In both instanc-
es, Fed officials relied on comforting data
analyses that betrayed breathtaking naivete
about the behavior of Wall Street wiseguys and
dynamics of financial markets.
Under the asymmetric monetary frame-
work that Bernanke lays out and the Fed now
embraces, the central bank will keep interest
rates “lower for longer” during recessions and
recoveries but won’t keep them higher for
longer when the economy is booming. The Fed
will print up trillions of dollars to fight one
recession but never manage to withdraw them
before the next one begins. To fight recessions,
it will encourage undue risk taking by specula-
tive investors, money managers and corporate
executives, providing them with oodles of
cheap money and assuring them that it won’t
be withdrawn anytime soon. And when the
inevitable bubble bursts and it all comes
crashing down, the Fed will be there once

politicians who have tried to politicize the Fed,
but sees no contradiction in describing how
the agency lobbied Congress in 2010 to pre-
serve its role as the leading bank regulator,
including recruiting the support for the banks
it regulates.
Bernanke seems to have forgotten his own
role, under a previous Fed chairman, in the
excessive consolidation and deregulation of
banks and financial markets that continue to
destabilize markets and the economy to this
day.
And even though it is more than a decade
since he left the Fed for a research sinecure at
the Brookings Institution, Bernanke clings to
the obfuscating and euphemistic language of
the central banker — insisting, for example,
that when the Fed buys trillions of dollars of
government bonds to stimulate the economy,
it does so not by “printing money” but by
“creating bank reserves.”
Particularly unconvincing is Bernanke’s as-
sertion that the expansionary monetary policy
he supports does not favor the rich or signifi-
cantly contribute to income inequality. Ber-
nanke acknowledges that one intended effect
of such policies is to artificially raise the price
of stocks and other financial assets that are
owned disproportionately by the rich. But he
argues that those policies also have a similar
effect of increasing employment, income
home values and retirement savings of the
middle and working classes.
Unfortunately, any broad look at the data
confirms what most of us see all around us:
that the dramatically increased wealth of
those in the top 10 percent overwhelms the
modest gains of everyone else as that wealth is
invested and converted to income. Bernanke’s
analysis betrays a surprisingly shallow under-

Book World

21ST CENTURY
MONETARY
POLICY
The Federal
Reserve from
the Great
Inflation to
COVID-1 9
By Ben S.
Bernanke
Norton.
480 pp. $35

THE FED
UNBOUND
Central
Banking in a
Time of Crisis
By Lev Menand
Columbia Global
Reports.
176 pp. $15.99.

F


ederal Reserve Chairman William Mc-
Chesney Martin spoke for generations of
monetary policymakers when he fa-
mously declared in 1955 that the job of the
central bank was to take away the punch bowl
“just when the party was really warming up.”
But in recent years, this puritanical ap-
proach to managing the ups and downs of the
economy had fallen into disrepute. Citing
structural changes in the economy and the
lessons learned from the two most recent
recessions, central bankers have come to be-
lieve that they must “do whatever it takes” to
pull an economy out of a serious downturn and
keep the cheap money flowing until the econo-
my has fully recovered — and then some.
Taking away the punch bowl too early, they
have come to believe, results in jobless recov-
eries in which the economy never reaches its
full potential and workers never gain the
leverage to bargain for a decent wage.
Among the intellectual godfathers for this
more muscular, run-it-hot monetary policy,
none is more respected than Ben Bernanke,
the Princeton academic who courageously and
creatively led the Fed into and through the
Great Recession. In his latest book, “21st
Century Monetary Policy: The Federal Reserve
from the Great Inflation to COVID-19,” Ber-
nanke aims to build public support for this
new monetary framework.
Unfortunately for Bernanke, however, his
book arrives just as this new framework is
being put to the test, with an inflationary
spiral taking hold, an economic slowdown on
the horizon, and tech and crypto bubbles
starting to burst. Earlier this month, as the
current Fed chair and his colleagues scram-
bled to hike interest rates and halt a multi-tril-
lion-dollar bond-buying spree, a somewhat-
chastened Jerome Powell admitted that they
had left the punch bowl out too long.
You can tell from its title that this is not a
book aimed at the bestseller list. Half is given
over to a history of Federal Reserve policy from
the Johnson administration to the present.
That is followed by a remarkably accessible
but unavoidably wonkish discussion of the
extraordinary steps taken by the Fed and other
central banks in the wake of the 2008 financial
crisis and then again during the recent pan-
demic. Readers will be treated to a spirited
defense of inflation-targeting but skepticism
toward nominal GDP-targeting; a nuanced
explanation of the difference between “for-
ward guidance” of the Delphic and Odyssean
varieties; a celebration of the success of “quan-
titative easing,” which has allowed central
banks to stimulate the economy even after
interest rates have fallen to zero; and an
impassioned plea for central bank independ-
ence from political interference. There’s even
an elegant put-down of Modern Monetary
Theory, a recently fashionable fantasy of un-
limited government borrowing that has cap-
tured the imagination of the libertarian right
and the free-spending left. Anyone looking for
the score settling, mea culpas and juicy anec-
dotes usually found in books by Washington
insiders will be disappointed.
Indeed, one of the weaknesses of the book is
that Bernanke cannot seem to bring himself to
say anything critical about any of his Fed
colleagues — or, for that matter, any of his
predecessors or successors — or the insular
Fed culture that remains smugly dismissive of
critics and dissenters, overreliant on its eco-
nomic models and willfully ignorant of the
machinations on Wall Street.
For example, Bernanke rightfully criticizes
former president Donald Trump and other

A former Fed chair still wants the punch bowl — and a high-proof punch

ECONOMY REVIEW BY STEVEN PEARLSTEIN

WIN MCNAMEE/GETTY IMAGES

F ederal Reserve
Board Chairman
Ben Bernanke
testifies before the
Senate Banking
Committee in 20 12.
Steven Pearlstein
writes that the
ideas Bernake lays
out in his new book
will be tested in the
months ahead.

again to do “whatever it takes” to rescue the
financial system and save risk-takers from the
full consequences of their actions.
This framework, in effect, creates a one-way
monetary ratchet that requires ever-increas-
ing doses of monetary stimulus to maintain
the economy at full employment, in the proc-
ess creating a floor under asset prices with
only a vague hint there might be a ceiling. Its
fixation on “forward guidance” about future
Fed moves invites everyone on financial mar-
kets to lean in the same direction while con-
straining the Fed from responding quickly to
changing conditions. And although Bernanke,
like his successors, may claim they’re doing it
all for the little guy, the clear message it sends
to the Wall Street is, We’ve Got Your Back!
In the coming months, the Fed will try to
rescue this strategy with a series of sharp rate
increases and gradual withdrawal of bank
reserves, moves that it hopes can tame infla-
tion without throwing the economy into reces-
sion. If the Fed succeeds in engineering such a
“soft landing,” Bernanke’s book could see a
second printing as it becomes the go-to text for
courses in monetary policy.
But if the strategy fails, the result is likely to
be an extended period of uncomfortably high
inflation and uncomfortably high unemploy-
ment. Such “stagflation” is confounding for
central bankers, as any move to solve one
problem is likely to exacerbate the other. In
that event, the most likely place to find a copy
of “21st Century Monetary Policy” will be the
remainder bin of your local bookstore.

Steven Pearlstein is a former business and
economics columnist for the Post. He is also the
Robinson Professor of Public Affairs at George
Mason University.

into U.S. dollars at a fixed rate — pose risks to
financial stability that remain unaddressed
more than a decade after the global financial
crisis.
Yes, Congress should expand automatic
stabilizers — enhanced unemployment ben-
efits, aid to state and local governments,
perhaps stimulus payments to low- and mod-
erate-income households — that turn on
when the economy stumbles and turn off
when it recovers.
Yes, Congress should do more to increase
the supply of housing to bring down its cost,
and make the health-care system more effi-
cient and less expensive, even though that
wouldn’t do much about today’s inflation.
Yes, the Fed is not the arm of the federal
government best suited to take the lead on
fighting climate change, even if elected politi-
cians are paralyzed.
Menand does offer a clear, textbook-style
history of the founding of the Fed and an

created by the [private] banking system does
not prevent the economy from achieving
these goals over the long term,” he says.
That may be what Woodrow Wilson and
Congress were thinking in 1913, but Menand
disregards more than half a century of
economic thought. He even declares in a
footnote that “arguments that the Fed should
raise interest rates to prevent prices from
rising above a certain annual rate are incon-
sistent with its mandate” because higher
interest rates discourage business invest-
ment. (He lost me there.)
Several of Menand’s policy recommenda-
tions are sound, even if the arguments he uses
to get to them are a bit tortured.
Yes, financial powerhouses outside the
perimeter of bank regulation — money mar-
ket mutual funds, investment firms whose
short-term borrowing resembles bank depos-
its and, lately, stablecoins, the crypto curren-
cies that promise holders can convert them

explanation of what it actually does in the
money markets; that alone is useful. He
correctly observes that in the fall of 2019 the
Fed intervened in the market for U.S. Treasury
debt because of dysfunction in that market,
which returned with vehemence in the early
days of the pandemic. And he briefly makes
the case, as he has elsewhere, that the Fed
should offer no-fee bank accounts to all “to
rectify predatory and exclusionary practices
in the investor-owned banking system that
have significantly harmed low-income and
minority communities by making it hard (if
not impossible) for many households to open
and maintain bank accounts.” He does not in
this volume, however, discuss the potential
for such accounts to destabilize the banking
system in a crisis, nor does he acknowledge
that this would substantially expand the role
of the Fed in the economy, a role that he thinks
is already too broad.
We do tend to ask too much of the Fed.
When the shadow banking system, its growth
insufficiently addressed by Congress and
regulators, threatens financial stability and
prosperity, we expect the Fed to save us. When
Congress is slow to rescue the economy from a
recession or turns the spigot off too soon (as it
did in pre-pandemic times), we count on the
Fed to do more. When elected politicians fail
to cope with some pressing problem —
inequality, climate change — there are inevi-
tably those (many aware that the Fed can
spend freely without congressional approval)
who demand that the Fed step in. And as
Menand argues, echoing warnings from Paul
Tucker, formerly of the Bank of England,
when unelected central banks tread too far
onto the turf of elected representatives, they
risk undermining their legitimacy and their
ability to achieve their mandate of maximum
employment and price stability.

W

hen the Federal Reserve came up
with $85 billion in 2008 to rescue
AIG, the insurance giant that gam-
bled and lost on derivatives, Rep. Barney
Frank, then chairman of the House Financial
Services Committee, asked Fed Chair Ben
Bernanke where he got all that money.
According to Frank, Bernanke responded: “I
have $800 billion,” referring to the Fed’s
portfolio of government bonds and loans.
Frank’s reply: “No one in a democracy, un-
elected, should have $800 billion to spend as
he sees fit. That’s not the way to run a
democracy.”
Lev Menand agrees.
A Columbia Law School associate professor
who did stints at the Obama Treasury Depart-
ment and the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, Menand argues in a slim paperback —
“The Fed Unbound: Central Banking in a
Time of Crisis” — that the Fed has been forced
to stray from its roots by the evolution of the
financial system, to which Congress has failed
to respond. The result, he argues, is that the
Fed has done too much and that this, among
other things, has widened wealth inequality
in the United States.
He largely absolves the Fed of blame for this
(though I would have noted that the Green-
span Fed was reluctant to use the regulatory
muscle it did have). Menand does, however,
suggest that if the Fed hadn’t been so quick to
act, Congress might have done more to repair
the flaws in financial oversight and macroeco-
nomic management that he identifies. “With
Fed-led macroeconomic policy tailor-made to
advance their interests,” he says, “why would
asset owners seek other responses from
Congress?”
The core of Menand’s historical and legal
argument is that the Fed was designed not to
stabilize the economy but solely “to adminis-
ter the banking system.” He argues that its
mandate is not to use its tools to deliver price
stability and maximum employment (as the
Fed itself and almost everyone else reads the
law) but, rather, to grow the money supply at a
rate consistent with the economy’s full poten-
tial. “Its job is to ensure that a lack of money

The problem with a Fed that does too much

ECONOMY REVIEW BY DAVID WESSEL

JABIN BOTSFORD/THE WASHINGTON POST

The Marriner S.
Eccles Federal
Reserve Board
Building in 20 19.
Lev Menand argues
that the Fed was
designed solely “to
administer the
banking system.”

David Wessel is the director of the Hutchins
Center on Fiscal and Monetary Policy at the
Brookings Institution and the author of “In Fed We
Trust: Ben Bernanke’s War on the Great Panic.” His
latest book is “Only the Rich Can Play,” the story of
Opportunity Zones.
Free download pdf