Rotman Management — Spring 2017

(coco) #1

114 / Rotman Management Spring 2017


something by 10 per cent, people will demand less of
it and supply will increase; but when you make some-
thing 10 per cent more salient in an interaction, depend-
ing on the environment, a wide variety of things can
happen. That’s why it is so important to understand the
decision-making context.

Why are insights from behavioural science so well suited
to the policy realm?
Because every policy relies on explicit and implicit as-
sumptions about how people make decisions and why they
do what they do. As indicated, most of those assumptions
rely on the rational, idealized model of how people think.
By embracing behavioural insights, we can redesign pub-
lic policies using new tools, including choice architecture;
social rewards and recognition; the way information is pre-
sented; and activating new social norms.

Your goal is to incorporate behavioural insights into some
of the World Bank’s work. How are you going about this?
We have three main criteria for selecting projects. The first
is, do they address an important developmental challenge?
Areas that address basic human rights are given high prior-
ity. Second, is the initiative ‘owned’ by the World Bank, or a
development partner? That is really important for sustain-
ability and ensuring a long-term impact. Then finally, can
the intervention be evaluated? At this stage of our work,
it’s really important to show that we’re having an impact,
so we look for projects where we can provide some form of
evaluation.
So far, our main areas of work are in tax compliance,
digital finance and savings, education, gender norms and
organizational effectiveness.

Why is this ‘extra work’ necessary?
Because time and again, we find that people have a very hard
time following through on their commitments. We might

want to save more, lose weight, or stop smoking, but we just
can’t follow through because we overvalue the present and
the willpower exertion is too large. Governments often of-
fer programs — from conditional cash transfers to health and
education programs — and are shocked when people don’t
take them up on it. This happens a lot, particularly in the
poorest environments. The question is, why? One reason is
that availing yourself of such programs requires effort and
takes time. Even though in the long run, it makes sense to
take advantage of the program, in the short run, people may
not have the bandwidth to do it.
As a result, all people — rich and poor alike — some-
times make choices that don’t promote their own well-being.
People may also get stuck in habits, succumb to inertia, and
repeatedly procrastinate despite intentions to do otherwise.
There was a study in Morocco in which the government
was providing a credit subsidy for a water hookup. Water
availability is a big problem there: people spend seven to
nine hours each week collecting water, and it is often the
women doing the work. Yet, people weren’t signing up for
the program. The researchers found that the problem was
the ‘hassle factor’ — making time to sign up for the pro-
gram. So, they decided to go directly to peoples’ homes
and get the necessary documentation, and they brought
it to the municipality. The result: the sign up rate went up
from a baseline of 10 per cent to 69 per cent! The implica-
tion is that making things easier for people can have a huge
impact.

Should governments be getting involved in shaping indi-
vidual choices?
I believe they should, for three reasons. First, doing so helps
people obtain their own goals. Reminders to save money
or take medicine help people achieve objectives that they
themselves have set. Research shows that commitment
contracts, which markets under-provide, can reinforce
decisions to adopt beneficial behaviours. Matching the

Development policy is due for a redesign, based on
a more realistic understanding of how people think.
Free download pdf