Rotman Management — Spring 2017

(coco) #1

122 / Rotman Management Spring 2017


bags; and price increases in gasoline have led consum-
ers to substitute more fuel-efficient vehicles and encour-
aged automakers to manufacture new vehicles with better
fuel economy.
Would a surcharge on unhealthy foods work as well as
these other sin taxes? In contrast to other types of sin tax-
es, we felt that a tax for less-healthy food might not func-
tion in a straightforward economic manner. For example,
people may believe that ‘higher-quality foods cost more’ or
are more ‘special’, thereby increasing the demand for un-
healthy meals that have been taxed. In addition, some peo-
ple may perceive the higher price to be a sign of healthiness
or freshness — rather than as a surcharge on unhealthiness.
Similar to price surcharges, we felt that unhealthy la-
bels on their own would have complex effects, because peo-
ple may use food labels to signal identities that they would

like to portray. For instance, gender stereotypes can signifi-
cantly affect the preference for healthy vs. unhealthy foods.
Research shows that a preference for healthier foods is rat-
ed as ‘more feminine’ and ‘less masculine’; and that women
are regarded as ‘more attractive’ when they eat fewer calo-
ries. However, unhealthy labels could backfire for men —
for whom eating high-fat foods is associated with masculin-
ity, whereas healthy eating is perceived as ‘wimpy’.
Men have also been shown to be less inclined to choose
products that are associated with women, and this effect is
magnified in public settings. Therefore, an unhealthy label
could actually encourage men to choose these items — par-
ticularly if they are eating with other men.
We also felt that the selection of unhealthy food might
reflect a temporary goal state. For example, unhealthy prod-
ucts tend to be preferred when a hedonic (i.e. pleasure) goal
is salient. Because unhealthy products are often perceived
as tastier, people often believe that if they work hard, they
have earned the right to indulge. Thus, an unhealthy label
could be construed as a sign of true indulgence and may ac-
tually encourage consumption.
We hypothesized that men would be more sensitive
to price increases when dining alone, but that a price in-
crease may not decrease unhealthy food consumption for
men when they are dining with others. We also expected
that an unhealthy label alone might backfire for men.
For women, we expected that an unhealthy label would
be more potent than a price surcharge. However, we ex-
pected that the combined effect of a price surcharge and
an unhealthy label (i.e., an ‘unhealthy surcharge’) would
be effective in reducing unhealthy choices for both men
and women.
As expected, we found significant gender effects: Men
significantly reduced unhealthy food choice when a simple
surcharge was added to unhealthy items, compared with

Almost half of our meals are now eaten in restaurants.

People often believe that if they work hard,
they have earned the right to indulge.
Free download pdf