The Economist UK - 07.09.2019

(Grace) #1

64 Finance & economics The EconomistSeptember 7th 2019


2

1

will not be sworn into office until Decem-
ber. But his words already have the power
to move markets and shape the economy.
His claim on August 30th that Argentina
was in “virtual default” deepened the mar-
ket sell-off (Standard & Poor’s, a rating
agency, also declared that there had been a
temporary, selective default on some of Ar-
gentina’s obligations). Creditors will not
renegotiate their debts with Mr Macri’s
lame-duck government, fearing that Mr
Fernández might force bigger concessions
later. The same worry may give pause to the
imf. Why should it give billions of addi-

tional dollars to Argentina, when its next
president accuses it of helping to create a
“social catastrophe” of rising prices, unem-
ployment and poverty?
Advisers to Mr Fernández say his cam-
paign rhetoric should not be taken too seri-
ously. “Alberto is acting now as a candida-
te...appealing to the base; he will govern
very differently,” says one of his inner cir-
cle. His chief economic adviser, Guillermo
Nielsen, has published a more moderate
ten-point agenda that leaves some room
for optimism. It recognises the need for a
budget surplus. And it envisages a “social

pact” between the unions and business to
tame inflation by moderating wage-claims
and price increases. A Peronist govern-
ment under Mr Fernández may find it easi-
er to bring the unions into line than today’s
government does. According to Federico
Sturzenegger, the former governor of Ar-
gentina’s central bank, Mr Macri’s adminis-
tration has eschewed that kind of dealmak-
ing because it “did not want to sit the
‘old-politics players’ at the decision table”.
The next government may even consid-
er much-needed reforms of labour laws
and welfare entitlements, according to

Buttonwood Tales of the expected


Premium model

Sources: Federal Reserve;
Standard & Poor’s

*Gap between S&P 500 earnings yield
and real five-year Treasury yields

United States, equity risk premium*
Percentage points

1997 2000 05 10 15 19

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

I

n 2011 john cochrane, a professor at
the University of Chicago’s Booth
School of Business, gave a presidential
address on “Discount Rates” to the Amer-
ican Finance Association. It was pub-
lished as a paper a few months later. In a
sweeping take, Mr Cochrane set out how
academics’ understanding of the way
asset prices are determined has shifted
over the past half-century. Many papers
are described as “landmark”; this one has
a better claim to the label than most.
His opening line (“Asset prices should
equal expected discounted cash flows”)
indicated that the basic premise has not
changed. But plenty has. In the 1970s the
focus of academic finance was on the
“expected” part of that equation—the
efficiency with which markets priced in
any new information relevant to future
cash flows. The emphasis has shifted.
The “discounted” part, or the risk prefer-
ences of investors, has become the main
organising principle for research, argued
Mr Cochrane.
The old-school view was that when
stock prices are high relative to earnings
or dividends (ie, yields are low), it im-
plies these cash flows are expected to
grow quickly in future. The new school
says it is changes in risk appetite—the
discount rate that investors apply to
future earnings—that explains much of
the variation in asset prices. If prices are
high and yields are low, that implies
investors are willing to accept lower
returns in future. Yields predict returns.
There are practical implications. A
generation ago an investor might have
looked to history for a guide to expected
returns. Now yields are seen as a more
useful steer. This is clearer with govern-
ment bonds. The real annual return on
American Treasury bonds was 1.9%
between 1900 and 2018, according to

Credit Suisse’s Global Investment Returns
Yearbook. But history is bunk. It would not
be wise to expect a 1.9% return when the
yield-to-maturity on inflation-protected
Treasury bonds is zero, as it is now.
The future cash flows from stocks are
not as certain as those from government
bonds. But Mr Cochrane argued that a
similar principle holds with stocks over
the long haul. “High prices, relative to
dividends, have reliably preceded many
years of poor returns. Low prices have
preceded high returns,” he said. The pre-
dictive power of yields holds for bonds and
stocks, but also for other assets, such as
housing. And valuations based on aggre-
gate earnings or book value predict stock
returns just as well as the dividend yield.
A lot of people prefer the earnings
yield. Share buy-backs have become a
more popular way to return capital to
stockholders than paying dividends. The
earnings yield may be a better guide to
expected returns. True, not all company
earnings are distributed to shareholders in
dividends or buy-backs; some are used to
pay for investment to generate future

earnings growth. On the other hand, that
growth should also be considered part of
expected returns.
If yields predict returns, that might
seem to imply that astute investors can
sell stocks when yields (and expected
returns) are low and buy them back when
yields are high. In practice, the signal
from yield is too weak to be relied upon
to catch turning points profitably. But
what matters to a lot of investors is not so
much what stocks will return in the short
run, but how much extra they will return
over safe bonds in the long run. This
extra reward is the equity risk pre-
mium—and to Mr Cochrane’s way of
thinking the discount rate, the risk pre-
mium and the expected return on equi-
ties “are all the same thing”. One forward-
looking measure of the equity risk pre-
mium shows a wide variation over time
(see chart). Investors with a long-term
horizon might profitably use such varia-
tions to decide on the mix of risky stocks
and safe bonds to hold in a portfolio. The
higher the risk premium on stocks, the
more the odds favour investors tilting
their portfolio away from bonds.
A question for academic research is
why exactly expected returns (or, if you
prefer, discount rates) on stocks vary so
much. One explanation is that, as memo-
ries of the previous market crash fade,
people get more comfortable owning
equities—until the next bear market
makes them rethink. In his address Mr
Cochrane argued that in a market slump
a typical investor is inclined to ignore the
high premiums offered by stocks be-
cause he fears for his job. The correlation
between employment income and stock
prices is to blame. Future returns are
remarkably hard to predict. Yields may
only be a weak guide to them; but they
are the best we have.

Why the earnings yield helps explain the mysteries of equity returns
Free download pdf