The Origins of Happiness

(Elliott) #1
Chapter 10

This is quite a high cost. So the policy maker might ask


a different question: Is there any other measure by which


I could raise the educational performance of a poor child?


As online Table A10.1 shows, there is a high correlation


between intellectual performance and the quality of sec-


ondary schooling. Anticipating Chapter 14, we find that


the difference in performance between the best and worst


performing three secondary schools in Avon (holding child


and parent characteristics constant) is 0.46 standard devi-


ations of GCSE points. Suppose it took £2,000 a year per


pupil to lift a school that far— or £10,000 over five years.


That would be an increase of 0.46 standard deviations per


£10,000— much more than could be achieved by a direct


income transfer to parents costing the same amount.


If you are wondering whether these results are too


negative about the quantitative impact of income on aca-


demic performance, they are in fact consistent with earlier


research.^9 For example Jo Blanden and Paul Gregg used


three earlier British datasets (BCS; BHPS; and the National


Child Development Study, NCDS) to examine how family


income at age 16 affected GCSE performance.^10 They con-


cluded that when family income falls by 33% the propor-


tion of children who obtain any GCSE A*- C grades falls by


3– 4 percentage points.^11 This corresponds to a β- coefficient


of around 0.1— similar to our estimate of 0.15.


For the United States, Daron Acemoglu and Jörn- Steffen


Pischke have used three longitudinal studies of school leav-


ers sponsored by the National Center for Education Sta-


tistics. These show that a 10% rise in family income leads


to a 1.4 percentage point rise in the probability of college


attendance, which implies a β- coefficient of around 0.14—


again similar.^12 Likewise at the earlier ages of three and five,

Free download pdf