The Ecology Book

(Elliott) #1
325
See also: Renewable energy 300–305 ■ Man and the Biosphere Programme
310–311 ■ Halting climate change 316–321

ENVIRONMENTALISM AND CONSERVATION


These damages include reductions
in agricultural productivity, harm to
infrastructure, energy costs, and
impacts on human health. The SCC
provides a starting point for energy
policy. For example, if the SCC is
factored into proposals for a new
power plant, the cost of building it
becomes much higher. This may
also make the cost of alternative
forms of energy—such as solar or
wind power—more financially
viable. However, it is extremely
difficult to calculate the SCC.

Forecast models
Economists use several models in
order to calculate the SCC. In 1999,
William Nordhaus developed RICE
(Regional Integrated Climate-
Economy model)—a variant of his
own preceding DICE (Dynamic
Integrated Climate-Economy model),
which weighed the costs and
benefits of slowing down global
warming. The RICE model
integrates carbon emissions, carbon
concentrations in the atmosphere,
climate change, damages, and
controls that are in place to reduce

emissions. The model divides the
world into distinct regions for its
analysis. It predicts that the
combined SCC in 2055 will be
between $40–$188 per ton ($44 and
$207 per tonne) of carbon dioxide
released, depending on the rate of
warming and the mitigation
policies enacted.
Economic models incorporate
assumptions, such as the discount
rate. Discount rates prioritize the
present over the future, because the
future cannot be predicted perfectly.
The rate is selected based on how
the balance between present and
future priorities is weighted. Higher
discount rates indicate that future
populations will be wealthier, and
prepared to deal with climate
change. Lower discount rates
suggest that the disruption caused
by climate change will make people
in the future poorer than we are
today. Nordhaus suggests a 3
percent discount rate, meaning that
if the monetary damages from
climate change will be $5 trillion in
the year 2100, we could invest $382
billion today to avoid it. ■

The cost of reducing
CO 2 increases in line
with the quantity, but
this is offset by the
benefits gained. The
lines intersect at the
point of equilibrium,
where maximum
benefits are achieved
at the lowest cost.

Analyzing the costs of reducing carbon dioxide


William Nordhaus


Born in New Mexico in 1941,
Nordhaus is a leader in the
field of the economics of
climate change. He stumbled
upon this field of research
through sharing an office with
a climatologist. Nordhaus’s
economic theories—the
DICE and RICE models—are
widely used to analyze policy
decisions. Nordhaus is
principally concerned with
placing a realistic price on
carbon. Today, the social cost
of carbon is generally agreed
to be around $40 per ton, but
Nordhaus’s models show that
it should be higher to account
for the impacts of climate
change. Nordhaus is Sterling
Professor of Economics at Yale
University, and serves on the
Congressional Budget Office
Panel of Economic Experts
and the Brooking Panel on
Economic Activity. In 2018,
Noordhaus was awarded the
Nobel Prize in economics.

Key works

1994 Managing the Global
Commons: The Economics
of Climate Change
2000 Warming the World:
Economic Models of Global
Warming

THE COST OF REDUCING CO

2

QUANTITY OF C0 2

Marginal
benefits

Financial
cost

US_324-325_Economics_of_climate_change.indd 325 17/12/2018 14:34

Free download pdf