Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
PART 4: CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND PAYOUT POLICY

The second investment opportunity (called ‘project Gold Coast’) is basically a gamble. It offers a 40%
chance of a $12-million payoff and a 60% chance of a $4-million payoff. Because its expected value is
only $7.2 million [(0.4 × $12,000,000) + (0.6 × $4,000,000)], project Gold Coast is a negative-NPV
‘investment’ that the company’s managers would reject if the company did not have debt outstanding.
However, if Gold Coast is successful, the project’s $12-million payoff will allow the company to fully pay
off the bonds and pocket a $2-million profit.
Consider the incentives facing this company’s managers. Clearly, bondholders want the managers
to either select the low-risk project or retain the company’s cash in reserve. But because shareholders
will lose control of the company unless they can pay off the bonds in full when they mature,
shareholders want the company’s managers to accept project Gold Coast. If successful, the project
will yield enough for shareholders to pay off the creditors and retain ownership of the company.
However, if Gold Coast is unsuccessful, the shareholders will simply hand over the company and
any remaining assets to bondholders, after defaulting on the maturing bonds. (Because of limited
liability, the corporation’s shareholders do not have to repay the bonds themselves.) This is also
what will happen if the company plays it safe by either retaining cash in the company or accepting
project Boring. Shareholders therefore have everything to gain and nothing to lose from accepting
project Gold Coast, and their agents (the managers) control the company’s investment policy until
default actually occurs.

The Underinvestment Problem


The second game related to financial distress is underinvestment. To demonstrate this, assume that the
company described above gains access to a very profitable, but short-lived investment opportunity. A
longtime supplier offers to sell its excess inventory to the company at a sharply discounted price, but
only if the company will pay for the inventory immediately with cash. The additional supplies will cost
$9 million today, but will allow the company to increase production and profitability dramatically over
the next 30 days. In fact, the company will be able to sell the additional product so profitably that in
30  days, it will build up the $10 million cash needed to pay off the maturing bond issue. However,
because the  company has only $8 million in cash on hand today, the company’s shareholders must
contribute  the additional $1 million needed to buy the supplier’s inventory. Accepting this project
would maximise overall company value and would clearly benefit the bondholders. But the shareholders
would rationally choose not to accept the project, because the shareholders would have to finance the
investment and all the investment’s payoff would accrue to the bondholders.
An all-equity company is not vulnerable to either of these two games associated with financial distress.
Managers acting in the interests of shareholders have the incentive to choose the project that maximises
company value, in the first example, and shareholders have the incentive to choose to contribute cash
for positive-NPV projects, in the second example. Because these costs of financial distress are related to
conflicts of interest between the two groups of security holders, they are also referred to as agency costs
of the relationship between bondholders and shareholders.

13 - 4b AGENCY COSTS AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE


In addition to taxes and the costs of financial distress, several other forces influence the corporate capital
structure choice. In 1976, Michael Jensen and William Meckling proposed an agency cost model of

underinvestment
When shareholders decide
not to invest in a positive
NPV project, and therefore
‘underinvest’ relative to
choosing all positive NPV
projects

Free download pdf