Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
15: Payout Policy

the company reinvest earnings rather than issue new shares? We reinforce dividend policy irrelevance
by demonstrating in the following Example that investors can unwind companies’ dividend policy
decisions. In the end, what is true for the company as a whole is true for each investor: Dividend policy
is irrelevant when capital markets are perfect.

example

Consider two investors, Bert and Ernie. On 1 January
2016, Bert owns an 11% stake (110,000 shares) in
Retention, whereas Ernie holds an 11% stake (also
110,000 shares) in Payout. By the end of 2016, Bert
has received no dividend but he still owns 11% of
Retention’s outstanding shares, which are now worth
$22 each. In contrast, Ernie receives a $220,000
dividend during 2016 but, because Payout issues
100,000 shares to finance its investment opportunity,
the shares Ernie owns now represent only a 10% stake
in payout (110,000 ÷ 1,100,000).
If either Bert or Ernie is unhappy with the dividend
policy of the company in which he has invested, he can
unwind that policy. For example, suppose Bert wishes
to receive cash as he would from a dividend. At the end

of 2016, Bert can sell 10,000 of his shares for $22 each,
generating a cash inflow of $220,000, exactly equal
to the dividend that Ernie receives on his investment.
In selling some of his shares, Bert creates homemade
dividends. By the end of the year, Bert owns just 10%
of Retention’s equity, but that’s exactly equal to the
ownership stake that Ernie holds in Payout.
Conversely, suppose that Ernie prefers that
Payout did not pay dividends. The solution to
Ernie’s problem is simple. When he receives the
$220,000 dividend, he simply reinvests the money
by purchasing 11,000 new Payout shares. That would
bring his total ownership to 121,000, or 11%, of
Payout’s shares (121,000 ÷ 1,100,000). In other words,
Ernie’s position is just like Bert’s.

This may seem complex, but the essential points of these examples are simple. If there were no
frictions or imperfections in capital markets, then investors would not care whether the company: (1)
retains earnings to fund positive-NPV investments or (2) pays dividends and sells new shares to finance
investments. In either case, cash flows from the company’s investments – not dividend decisions –
determine shareholders’ returns.

15-3b MILLER AND MODIGLIANI MEET THE (IMPERFECT)
REAL WORLD

In the previous section, we saw that when capital markets are perfect and frictionless, payout decisions
do not affect company value. The core of the idea behind Miller and Modigliani’s argument is that
operational and investment decisions, not financial policies, are what create value. However, in Figure 15.3
we saw that corporate managers say that maintaining the existing dividend payment ranks ahead of
investment decisions at many companies. This is the starkest possible rejection of the Miller and
Modigliani irrelevance argument, because it implies that a financial decision (of maintaining dividends)
is more important than the investment decision.
How can this be the case? Here we discuss several academic theories that explain why payout
decisions do matter. Each of these theories describes why a certain market imperfection (such as taxes
or agency costs) affects payout decisions in general or the choice between dividends and repurchases.

LO15.4


See the concept explained
step by step on the
CourseMate website.

SMART
CONCEPTS
Free download pdf