The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

120


T


here has long been
something appealing
for economists about the
idea that the economy may behave
with the same mathematical
predictability of scientific laws
such as Newton’s laws of motion.
Newton’s laws reduce the whole
complex, teeming, physical
universe to three simple, reliable
mathematical relationships.
Is it possible to find similar
relationships in the complex,
changing world of markets?
In 1851, a British professor
named Francis Edgeworth
published Mathematical Psychics,
an early mathematical work
on economics. He realized that
economics deals with relationships
between variables, which means
that it can be translated into
equations. Edgeworth thought
about economic benefits in
utilitarian terms. In other words
believing that outcomes could
be measured in terms of units of
happiness, or pleasure.
Other economists were
also intrigued by the idea of
a mathematical approach. In
Germany the economist Johann
von Thünen developed equations

for a fair working wage and the
most profitable use of land. In
France Léon Walras, an academic
who would later be described as
“the greatest of all economists,”
was trying to discover a complete
mathematical, scientific framework
for the entire discipline. Walras
was ardent in his conviction
that it was possible to discover
economic laws that would make
economics a “pure moral science”
(describing human behavior) that
went hand in hand with the “pure
natural science” of Newton. His

Léon Walras Marie Esprit Léon Walras was
born in Normandy, France, in


  1. As a young man he was
    captivated by bohemian Paris, but
    his father persuaded him that one
    of the romantic tasks of the future
    was to make economics a science.
    Walras was convinced—though he
    maintained his bohemian life
    until, destitute, he went to
    Lausanne as economics professor
    in 1870. It was there he developed
    his theory of general equilibrium.
    Walras believed that the
    organization of society was a
    matter of “art” outside the
    scientific realm of economics.


He had a strong sense of social
justice and campaigned for land
nationalization as a prelude to
equal land distribution. In 1892,
he retired to the town of Clarens
overlooking Lake Geneva, where
he fished and thought about
economics until he died in 1910.

Key works

1874 Elements of Pure
Economics
1896 Studies in Social
Economics
1898 Studies in Applied
Economics

ECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM


IN CONTEXT


FOCUS
Markets and firms

KEY THINKER
Léon Walras (1834 –1910)

BEFORE
1851 Francis Edgeworth
publishes a mathematical
assessment of economics in
Mathematical Psychics.

AFTER
1906 Vilfredo Pareto develops
a new theory of equilibrium
that takes account of the
compatibility of individual
incentives and constraints.

1930s John Hicks, Oskar
Lange, Maurice Allais, Paul
A. Samuelson, and others
continue to develop the theory
of general equilibrium.

1954 Kenneth Arrow and
Gérard Debreu provide a
mathematical proof of
general equilibrium.

Léon Walras argued that the sum of
all the excess demand in an economy
equals zero. In an economy with just
apples and cherries, excess demand for
apples means excess supply of cherries.
Free download pdf