The Economics Book

(Barry) #1

290


In “first generation”
crisis models, when
one currency is fixed to
another, its “real” value,
or shadow rate, may fall
below the value at which
it is fixed. In this case
this is the point at
which the shadow
exchange rate rises
above 2 pesos/$1.
When this happens, the
currency is vulnerable
to attack as speculators
buy the country’s
foreign currency
reserves in anticipation
of a devaluation.

IN CONTEXT


FOCUS
Global economy

KEY THINKER
Paul Krugman (1953– )

BEFORE
1944 Greece experiences
the largest currency crash
in history.

1978 US economic historian
Charles Kindleberger stresses
the role of irrational behavior
in crises.

AFTER
2009 US economists Carmen
Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff
publish This Time is Different:
Eight Centuries of Financial
Folly, in which they draw
similarities between crises
over the centuries.

2010–12 Divergent national
priorities, serious policy
errors, and huge speculative
pressures threaten the
breakup of the euro.

SPECULATION AND CURRENCY DEVALUATION


when money was based on
precious metals, a currency usually
lost its value through currency
debasement, which occurred when
a ruler reduced the precious metal
content of the coinage. After money
began to be printed on paper by
central banks, high inflation would
cause a country’s currency to
collapse. This happened in
Germany in 1923, where at one
point prices were doubling every
two days. However, a country does
not need hyperinflation to have a
currency crisis. For example during
the Great Depression of 1929–33,
prices of commodities such as
minerals and food collapsed, and
the currencies of Latin American
countries, which were reliant on
this export trade, fell with them.

Inconsistent policies
Writing in 1979, US economist
Paul Krugman showed that for a
currency crisis to happen, all that is
needed is for a government to carry
out policies that are inconsistent
with the exchange rate.
Krugman’s argument is the
foundation for a first generation of
currency crisis models. These
models start by assuming that
there is a fixed exchange rate
between the home currency and an
external currency, and that the
home government is running a
budget deficit (it is spending more
than it is collecting in tax), which
it is financing by printing money.
By increasing the supply of the
currency, this policy creates an
inconsistency with the value of the
currency set by the fixed exchange
rate. Other things being equal, the
policy will cause the “real” value
of the home currency to fall.
Next, the models assume
that the central bank sells its own
reserves of foreign currency in order
to support the currency. However,

A


currency crisis is a large
and sudden collapse in
the value of one nation’s
currency relative to other currencies.
For about 30 years after World
War II the world’s main currencies
were governed by the Bretton
Woods system (pp.186–87),
which was based on fixed, but
adjustable, exchange rates.
When this system ended in
1971, currency crises became more
common. In general a currency
crisis is triggered by people selling
a country’s currency in large
amounts. This behavior seems
to stem from the interaction of
people’s expectations and certain
underlying economic weaknesses
(known as “fundamentals”)—in
other words people’s reactions to
perceived problems. Economists
have tried to model this interaction
mathematically, but every time they
think they have found a model that
fits the data, a new type of crisis
seems to emerge.

Currency crises in context
Like hurricanes, financial crises
happen surprisingly often but are
hard to predict. Centuries ago,

EXCHANGE RATE (PESOS PER $)

Shadow rate
starts at 1.5
pesos/$1 but
rises over time

Fixed rate

Fixed rate is
2 pesos/$1

TIME

Currency is
attacked when
the shadow rate
rises above the
fixed rate

0
Free download pdf