The Mathematics of Financial Modelingand Investment Management

(Brent) #1

14-Arbitrage Page 401 Wednesday, February 4, 2004 1:08 PM


Arbitrage Pricing: Finite-State Models 401

Prices can then be expressed as

M M M
S ψj

i = ∑ dijψj = ∑ pjdij----- = ∑ pjdijπj

j = 1 j = 1 pj j = 1

which demonstrates that S = E[Dππππ].
We can now specialize the above calculations in the numerical case
of the previous section. Recall that in the previous section we gave the
example of three securities with the following prices and payoffs
expressed in dollars:

S =

70
60
80

D =

50 100
30 120
38 112

We first compute the relative state prices:

50 ψ 1 + 100 ψ 2 = 70
30 ψ 1 + 120 ψ 2 = 60
38 ψ 1 + 112 ψ 2 = 80

Solving the first two equations, we obtain

ψ 1
ψ 2

⁴₅
³₁₀

=

However, the third equation is not satisfied by these values for the state
prices. As a consequence, there does not exist a state-price vector which
confirms that there are arbitrage opportunities as observed in the first
section.
Now suppose that the price of security C is $64 and not $80. In this
case, the third equation is satisfied and the state-price vector is the one
shown above. Risk-neutral probabilities can now be easily computed.
Here is how. First sum the two state prices: ⁴₅ + ³⁄₁₀ = ¹¹⁄₁₀ to obtain
Free download pdf