Attitudes to risk and expected value
Figure 6.7
Graph of the
probabilities of
the NPV for two
projects each
having equal
expected NPVs
Although both projects have identical expected NPVs, the ranges of possibilities differ
between them. A risk-averse investor would prefer Project A. This is because the worst
possible outcome is an NPV of £9,000, which is quite a lot higher than the minimum outcome
from Project B.
would be more attracted to Project B. A risk-neutral investor would be unable to dis-
tinguish between these two projects.
Expected value and the business’s investment decisions
From what we have seen above, in deciding on risky investment projects we cannot
directly translate the wealth maximisation rule into one of expected wealth maxim-
isation: in other words, we cannot simply take on all available projects with a positive
expected NPV. The reason for this is that shareholders are probably all risk-averse.
The situation is complicated still further by the fact that they probably show different
degrees of risk aversion (differently shaped utility curves and different levels of
wealth). An investment with a risk/return profile that might be acceptable to one
shareholder may not be acceptable to another.
This potential lack of unanimity may seem familiar. It is, of course, analogous to the
investment decision without the borrowing/lending facility (a matter that we dis-
cussed in Chapter 2), and it poses the same problem. How do managers make their
investment decisions when shareholders take different attitudes to risk? As before, it
is really the utility, or satisfaction of wealth, that shareholders want maximised, but
shareholders will not necessarily all agree on what satisfies them most. Maximisation
of the utility of wealth involves some consideration of the range of possible outcomes
(as is evident from Figure 6.5).