In the case of the parameters used for the table in section 4.2.,
q
=0.28 and q–=0.95.
There is no loss of generality in restricting the support of qtto the
interval [q
,q–]. Certainly, an investor can have prior beliefs that lie
outside this interval, but with probability one, qtwill eventually be-
long to this interval, and will then stay within the interval forever.
We are now ready to begin the main argument of the proof. Un-
derreaction means that the expected return following a positive
shock should exceed the expected return following a negative shock.
In other words,
Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=+y)−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=−y)>0.
Overreaction means that the expected return following a series of
positive shocks is smaller than the expected return following a series
of negative shocks. In other words, there exists some number J≥1,
such that for all j≥J,
Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=yt− 1 =...=yt−j=y)
−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=yt− 1 =...=yt−j=−y)<0.
Proposition 2 provides sufficient conditions on p 1 and p 2 so that
these two inequalities hold. A useful function for the purposes of
our analysis is
f(q)=Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=+y, qt=q)−Et(Pt+ 1 −Ptyt=−y, qt=q).
The function f(q) is the difference between the expected return
following a positive shock and that following a negative shock,
where we also condition on qtequaling a specific value q. It is sim-
ple enough to write down an explicit expression for this function.
Since
we find
E( , ) ()
()() ()
()(()())
ttPPy yqqtt t
y
yp q
y
yp pq yp q yp q
ypq p yp q q
+ −=+== +
+−− − − +
=−+ +
12
12 2 2
21
1
2 2
1
2
1
2
22
δ
δ
∆
∆∆
∆∆
PP
y
yyppqypqq
yypqq
tt
t
tt tttt
tttt
+
+
++
++
−= + − − − −
−− −
1
1
112 21
121
δ
()( )()
()(),
454 BARBERIS, SHLEIFER, VISHNY