Frequently Asked Questions In Quantitative Finance

(Kiana) #1
Chapter 4: Ten Different Ways to Derive Black–Scholes 267

compensation in excess of the risk-free rate for taking
unit amount of risk must be the same for each.

For the stock, the expected return (dividing bydt)isμ.
Its risk isσ.

From Itˆowehave

dV=

∂V
∂t

dt+^12 σ^2 S^2

∂^2 V
∂S^2

dt+

∂V
∂S

dS.

Therefore the expected return on the option is

1
V

(
∂V
∂t

+^12 σ^2 S^2

∂^2 V
∂S^2

+μS

∂V
∂S

)

and the risk is
1
V

σS

∂V
∂S

.

Since both the underlying and the option must have the
same compensation, in excess of the risk-free rate, for
unit risk

μ−r
σ

=

1
V

(
∂V
∂t+

1
2 σ

(^2) S 2 ∂^2 V
∂S^2
+μS∂∂VS
)
1
VσS
∂V
∂S
.
Now rearrange this. Theμdrops out and we are left
with the Black–Scholes equation.


Utility Theory


The utility theory approach is probably one of the least
useful of the ten derivation methods, requiring that we
value from the perspective of an investor with a utility
function that is a power law. This idea was introduced
by Rubinstein (1976).
Free download pdf