388 The Basics of financial economeTrics
Given a square n × n matrix A, the matrix dgA is the diagonal matrix
extracted from A. The diagonal matrix dgA is a matrix whose elements are
all zero except the elements on the diagonal which coincide with those of
the matrix A:
=
⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅ ⋅⋅
⋅⋅ ⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅
⇒=
⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅⋅
⋅⋅ ⋅⋅
⋅⋅ ⋅⋅
⋅⋅⋅
aa a
aa a
aa a
a
a
a
AAdg
00
00
00
n
n
nn nn nn
11 12 1
21 22 2
12
11
22
The trace of a square matrix A is the sum of its diagonal elements:
=∑
=
trA aii
i
n
1
A square matrix is called symmetric if the elements above the diago-
nal are equal to the corresponding elements below the diagonal: aij = aji. A
matrix is said to be a skew-symmetric if the diagonal elements are zero and
the elements above the diagonal are the opposite of the corresponding ele-
ments below the diagonal: aij = –aji.
The most commonly used symmetric matrix in financial econometrics
and econometrics is the covariance matrix, also referred to as the variance-
covariance matrix. For example, suppose that there are N risky assets and
that the variance of the excess return for each risky asset and the covari-
ances between each pair of risky assets are estimated. As the number of
risky assets is N, there are N^2 elements, consisting of N variances (along the
diagonal) and N^2 − N covariances. Symmetry restrictions reduce the number
of independent elements. In fact the covariance between risky asset i and
risky asset j will be equal to the covariance between risky asset j and risky
asset i. Hence, the variance-covariance matrix is a symmetric matrix.
Determinants
Consider a square, n × n, matrix A. The determinant of A, denoted A, is
defined as follows:
A=−()()
=
∑^1 ∏
1
1
tj j
ij
i
n
,...,n a