The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_C Date:31/3/09
Time:21:45:54 Filepath://ppdys1108/BlackwellCup/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-
9781405132879/appln/3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_C.3d


Ground Zero in New York City had become a
small marketplace for 9/11 T-shirts and other
mementos, just as shirts bearing the image of
Osama Bin Laden and the falling towers were
selling like hot cakes in Bangkok, Jakarta and
the West Bank as icons of anti-imperialism.
We began with the commodity as a trivial
thing and have ended with a world of com-
modities that ‘actually conceals, instead of dis-
closing, the social character of private labour,
and the social relations between the individual
producers’ (Marx, 1976 [1867], pp. 75–6).
But this hidden history of the commodity
allows us to expose something unimaginably
vast; namely, the dynamics and history of cap-
italism itself. The commodity as its ‘cellular
form’ is surely one of the keys to unlocking the
secrets of what Max Weber (2001 [1904–5])
called the ‘capitalist cosmos’. mw

Suggested reading
Taussig (1978).

commodity chain/fili


ere A collection of
interrelated economic activities and industries
that produce a particular kind of product or
service. While commodity chains connote
‘vertical’ coordination among firms, from
design to assembly to final distribution, the
term seems to have first been used by
Hopkins and Wallerstein in 1977 in a pro-
grammatic call to de-centre thenation-state
in international political economy. Coming
from the perspective of world systems theory
(seecore–periphery model), they argued for
attention to be paid to ‘the widespread com-
modification of processes’ by ‘tak[ing] an
ultimate consumable item and trac[ing] it
back to the set of inputs that culminated in
this item – the prior transformations, the raw
materials, the transportation mechanisms, the
labor input into each of the material processes,
the food inputs into the labor’ (p. 128). The
alternative – and more common – usage of
this concept seems to have independent ori-
gins in French industrial economics. Montfort
and Dutailly (1983) used the termfilie`reto
refer to a set of firms linked vertically in the
creation of a single product. The organiza-
tional structure of an economy is then best
understood and described as a collection of
constituent filie`res, or commodity chains.
This approach has been used ineconomic
geographyto discuss technological and eco-
nomic interdependencies between spatially
proximate buyers and suppliers, as well as
firms linked horizontally in relations of co-
operation. The approach also appears to have

independent origins in agro-food studies (see
agro-food system), representing a rare case
in whichagricultural geographyled the
way in economic geography. Friedland,
Barton and Thomas (1981) first use of the
term ‘commodity systems analysis’ to focus
on the mutual interaction of agricultural pro-
duction practices, grower organization,
labour, science and extension, and marketing
and distribution systems, which was quickly
followed by the actor-oriented variant associ-
ated with Wageningen University to empha-
size how the specificity of farm labour
processes can give rise to different styles of
farming(van der Ploeg, 1985).
For some scholars, the utility of commodity
chains is largely descriptive, a lens through
which to examine industrial organization and/
or economic geography. For instance, the
global commodity chain approach, most asso-
ciated with Gary Gereffi and his colleagues,
focuses on the transnational reach of inter-
firm networks of manufacturers, suppliers
and subcontractors to each other, and to mar-
kets. In respect to the strong coordination role
that apparel design firms started to play in the
1980s, they also suggested an epochal shift
from producer-driven to buyer-driven chains.
Recently, they have posited the existence of
regulation- or consumer-driven commodity
chains, in light of the increased salience of
ethical products and the increasing power of
private systems of regulation to construct and
ensure quality in certain spheres of commodity
production (see Gereffi, Humphrey and
Sturgeon, 2005).
One variation on this approach is value
chain analysis, which draws attention to how
surplus distribution along a given chain is a
function of rent-generating barriers to entry,
which are in turn a function of chain govern-
ance (Kaplinsky, 2004). Kaplinsky and
others have argued that that nationaldevel-
opmentprospects can be improved by indus-
trial ‘upgrading’ to higher value-added
processes.
For another set of scholars, the commodity
chain approach is a tool of radical scholarship,
in that it has the potential to make the work-
ings ofcapitalismmore transparent, particu-
larly becauseglobalizationseems to make
most commodities inscrutable as to how they
are made and distributed (Hartwick, 1998).
Other geographers, notably Leslie and
Reimer (1999), are critical of the notion that
commodities can be ‘unveiled’. Leslie and
Reimer have also remarked that commodity
chains privilegeflowsrelative toscale. jgu

COMMODITY CHAIN/FILI


ERE

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_C Final Proof page 101 31.3.2009 9:45pm
Free download pdf