Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_P Date:1/4/09
Time:15:20:53 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/re-
vises/9781405132879_4_P.3d
1986). Critics have pointed out that even
standardized and mature products can be reju-
venated through innovation in the later stages
of a product’s life cycle. A case in point is the
automobile which, while hardly a new product,
has been continuously modified and improved
over time. It has also been argued that many
commoditiesnever achieve the status of cheap,
standardized, mass-produced goods – especially
those that, under a regime ofpost-fordism,
exhibit a high degree of variability, customiza-
tion and qualitative differentiation. msg
Suggested reading
Malecki (1991).
production complex A spatial cluster of spe-
cialized, interrelated economic activities bound
together by the creation and exploitation of
external economies(Scott, 1988b). Such
clustersoffer producers the ability to estab-
lish, and easily realign, transactionallinkages
with other local buyers and suppliers, thereby
encouraging the development and mainten-
ance of a social division of labour (seejust-in-
time production;transaction costs;trans-
actional analysis). They also provide a local
labour marketspecialized to match the needs
of local producers. They are further sustained
by the existence of public and quasi-public
institutions developed to support specialized
local economic activity and to foster non-mar-
ketforms of interaction and interdependencies
between local economic actors. (Seeagglom-
eration;commodity chain/filiE`re;indus-
trial district.) msg
production of nature This rather strikingly
counter-intuitive phrase comes from Neil
Smith, originally in his bookUneven develop-
ment(1984). Despite its critics, perhaps noth-
ing attests to the power of the idea more than
the fact that the phrase becomes less counter-
intuitive with time.
At the simplest level, and clearly influenced
by Lefebvre’s understanding of theproduc-
tion of space, Smith conveys by this phrase
thatnatureis socially produced and, more
specifically, that nature is increasingly an arte-
fact ofcapitalismin the contemporary world.
At one level, this is not so counter-intuitive at
all. Increasingly, atscalesfrom the atmos-
pheric to the genetic, the material natures of
everyday lifeare increasingly transformed
either by intentional manipulation for the pur-
poses ofcommodityproduction (e.g. genetic-
ally modified crops), or by the myriad
ecological impacts of industrial, capitalist
activities and related processes (e.g. the depos-
ition of persistent organic pollutants in Arctic
and Antarctic ecosystems). Since Smith’s
book, empirical processes that confirm the
material production of nature to suit economic
purposes have proliferated, including the
onset of commercial aquaculture and the con-
tinuedglobalizationof plantationforestry.
Moreover, empirical research has elaborated
Smith’s thesis, indicating that the capitalist
production of nature, often in shifting and
complex institutional configurations, has been
ongoing for some time (Prudham, 2003).
While agriculture would be the most obvious
example to draw on here, under which the
intentional transformation of crops andani-
malsis probably in excess of 10,000 years
old, Smith is at pains to differentiate the cap-
italist production of nature from all that has
come before it. This is not, as he argues,
because widespread anthropogenic change is
unique to capitalism (quite the opposite).
Rather, it is because the particular ways that
nature is transformed under capitalism are
unique. This includes, for instance, the appro-
priation and transformation of biophysical
processes as a constitutive facet ofuneven
developmentunder capitalism. An elabor-
ation of this, with some qualification, can be
found in Robbins and Fraser (2003), who note
‘... if the state can put non-commercial Scots
pine woodland in the place of industrial for-
ests, it is only, after all, because increased
extraction is occurring in the Baltic states,
Indonesia, and Ghana .. .’ (p. 113). Here,
produced nature is worked through as a com-
plex set of spatial and scalar logics that link
far-flung places, not least throughmarket
relations andexchange, as well as in the realm
of productionper se.
However, Smith’s thesis is not only about
the material transformation of nature under
capitalism. Rather, he also posits that a unique
feature of what might be called ‘capitalist
nature’ is the ways in which ideas about nature
are also produced in and through capitalist
production, commodity circulation, and cap-
italist social relations and institutions. This is a
complex and controversial thesis. Yet, at one
level, Smith’s observation is no different than
those who have long recognized the rise of
instrumental, utilitarian thinking alongside
industrial capitalism. Smith’s argument is that
such an instrumentalist disposition specifically
towards nature is reinforced by capitalist social
relations and processes of valuation, and that
these ideas become increasingly influential in
the construction of meaning around nature in
Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_P Final Proof page 589 1.4.2009 3:20pm
PRODUCTION OF NATURE