The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: VPugazhenthi Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_S Date:1/4/
09 Time:15:23:36 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/
revises/9781405132879_4_S.3d


and associated urbanization (termed a
society’s ‘increasing scale’: Shevky and Bell,
1955). Increasing scale (not to be confused
with other uses of that term – seescale)
involves three interrelated trends:

. Changes in the range and intensity of so-
cial relations produced by greaterdivision
of labourand reflected in the distribution
of skills and rewards within society – this
trend was termedsocial rankoreconomic
status.
. Increasing differentiation of functions within
society and its constituent households
generating new lifestyles and household
forms – termedurbanizationorfamily status.
. The concentration into cities of people
from different cultural backgrounds– seg-
regationorethnic status.


The link between these three trends and resi-
dential differentiation was not clear in the ori-
ginal presentation. Shevky and Bell selected
variables to represent the three trends (the
percentage in certain occupations for eco-
nomic status, for example), which were meas-
ured for the variouscensus tractsin a city
and used to produce standardized indices for
each tract on each construct. The tracts were
then classified into a typology of social areas
depending on their values on the three indices.
Although the technique was soon super-
seded by the more inductive approach of
factorial ecology, and the theory was
largely ignored withinurban geography, the
three constructs remained central to much
analysis of urban residential patterns. rj

Suggested reading
Johnston (1969).

social capital The idea that access to and
participation in groups can benefit individuals
and communities – the nub of contempo-
rary social capital scholarship – is a well-
established sociological insight dating to the
nineteenth century writings of Karl Marx,
Emile Durkheim and Ferdinand Tonnies,
among others. The term itself was first
invoked (and then only once) by the econo-
mist Glen Loury in a 1977 article in which he
critiqued neo-classical theories of racial
income inequality. Loury contended that by
its commitment to methodological individ-
ualism, orthodox labour economics was
incapable of factoring how social context –
specifically, poorer connections of young black
workers to the labour market and their lack of

information about opportunities – impeded
intergenerational mobility and reproduced
race divisions rooted in economic inequality
(Loury, 1977).
The sociologist Alejandro Portes (1998)
attributes the first theoretically refined analysis
of social capital to Pierre Bourdieu, who
defined the concept as ‘the aggregate of the
actual or potential resources which are linked
to possession of a durable network of more or
less institutionalized relationships of mutual
acquaintance or recognition’ (Bourdieu,
1985, p. 248). Although Bourdieu’s note, ini-
tially published in French in 1980, remained
neglected within the English-speaking world,
the concept of social capital proliferated,
catalysed by a conjuncture of events. These
included the publication of an article in the
late 1980s by a leading American sociologist,
James Coleman, in which he explored the con-
nection between aspects of ‘social structure’
and ‘human capital’ formation (Coleman,
1988). Although Coleman’s treatment of
social capital lacked the rigour of Bourdieu’s
formulation, it garnered far more traction.
Post-1989markettriumphalism, accompany-
ing receptivity within and outside academia
(e.g. at powerful multinational institutions
such as the World Bank) to non-dirigiste
sources of economicdevelopment, and the
linked emergence of a ‘globalcivil society’
discourse (which conflated ideas of free society
and free market) undoubtedly contributed to
the popularity of Coleman’s thesis.
Since then, mainstream social science has
operationalized the concept of social capital in
a bewildering number of ways. The shared
impulse has been to parlayculturein a form
sensible to economics and policy science. This
importation of culture into the economic is
sorely inadequate (see cultural economy).
Of the three broad categories of empirical
approaches currently in vogue, the first evalu-
ates how social relations might function as
collateral or assurance that an economic trans-
action will occur in the manner anticipated –
the distilled wisdom here is that social capital in
the form oftrustminimizes the risks (and,
hence, costs) associated with transactions and
boosts economic competitiveness. A second
approach measures how social capital as density
of strong and weak social ties and group
membership acts as an insurance mechanism
during periods of need or crisis – the contention
being that social cohesion is positively correl-
ated with the ability of individuals to shield
themselves from idiosyncratic risks. A third
approach conceptualizes social capital as a

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_S Final Proof page 689 1.4.2009 3:23pm

SOCIAL CAPITAL
Free download pdf