The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: VPugazhenthi Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_S Date:1/4/
09 Time:15:23:40 Filepath:H:/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-9781405132879/appln/3B2/
revises/9781405132879_4_S.3d


closely associated with the work of the
Canadian economic historian Harold A. Innis
(1894–1952). In Innis’ account, and the basis
for the school of Canadianpolitical econ-
omy, staples production creates economic
instability and hinterland dependency for
staples-producing regions. At least three
causes are at work:

(1) marketsfor staplecommoditiesapproxi-
mate more closely perfect competition
than do those for manufactured goods.
Staples regions are price-takers in markets
where unpredictability is the norm,
producing cycles of boom and bust.
(2) For a variety of reasons (technological
innovationsthat reduce resource inputs
for production, the growth of synthetic
substitutes, and low long-run income
elasticities of demand), the terms of
trade for primary commodities are in-
creasingly less favourable to staples-
producing areas.
(3) resourceextraction or production tends
to be undertaken by large, often foreign-
owned,transnational coroporations.
Spry (1981) argues that this is a direct
consequence of the large capital expend-
itures and production indivisibilities asso-
ciated with staples. The presence of such
firms in staples regions creates a number
of potential problems for the region in-
cluding: the appropriation of economic
rentsbecause of the undervaluing of re-
sources by thelocal statein order to
induce investment; the failure to process
the staple prior to export (and where
value-added occurs) because resource ex-
traction is only one stage within a verti-
cally integrated corporation that for
reasons of internal control locates manu-
facture elsewhere; the low levels of tech-
nological innovation and development;
the lack of local control; and finally, a
weakened ability to control trade thro-
ugh explicit policy because of the high
degree of intra-corporate transfers.

For Innis, there is thus a direct relationship
between the type oftradein which a staples
region engages and its level of social and
economic development. This contradicts the
orthodox neo-classical theory of trade (see
neo-classical economics), which would
maintain that a staples nation such as
Canada benefits from specializing in and
exchanging those commodities in which it pos-
sesses a comparative advantage, namely

primary resources. But in drawing upon this
theory, as Innis (1956 [1929], p. 3) wrote in
the late 1920s, economists ‘attempt to fit their
analysis of new economic facts into ... the eco-
nomic theory of old countries ... The handi-
caps of this process are obvious, and there is
evidence to show that [this is]. .. a new form of
exploitation with dangerous consequences.’.
To circumscribe such exploitation, Innis
developed his theory in such a way that it
was peculiarly suited to the economic facts
of staples regions. He brought together three
types of concerns: geographical/ecological,
institutional and technological (Barnes,
1996, ch. 8). Innis argued that when the right
technology came together with the right geog-
raphy and the right institutional structure, the
result wasaccumulationof ‘cyclonic’ frenzy.
In this way, virgin resource regions were
transformed and enveloped within the pro-
duced spaces of the capitalist periphery.
Such intense accumulation, however, never
lasts, and because of the very instabilities of
staples production, sooner rather than later
investment shifts to yet other staples regions,
leaving in its wake abandoned resource sites
and communities. As countries such as
China and India rapidly industrialize, draw-
ing in immense flows of staples commodities,
transforming regions and creating shudders
across the world’s resources sites, Innis’ the-
ory has never been more relevant (Hayter,
Barnes and Bradshaw, 2003). tb

Suggested reading
Barnes (1996, ch. 8); Drache (1995).

state A centralized set of institutions facili-
tating coercive power and governing capabil-
ities over a defined territory. No one
definition of the state is adequate given the
way that states have varied in their form and
function over time and space. However,
Michael Mann (1984a) has identified the def-
initional need to incorporate both institutional
and functional concerns, or what the state
looks like and what it does. His subsequent
definition can be summarized as follows:

(1) a set of institutions and their related per-
sonnel;
(2) a degree of centrality, with political de-
cisions emanating from this centre point;
(3) a definedboundarythat demarcates the
territorial limits of the state; and
(4) a monopoly of coercivepowerandlaw-
making ability (Jones, Jones and Woods,
2004, p. 20).

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_S Final Proof page 722 1.4.2009 3:23pm

STATE
Free download pdf