The Dictionary of Human Geography

(nextflipdebug2) #1

Comp. by: LElumalai Stage : Revises1 ChapterID: 9781405132879_4_T Date:31/3/09
Time:21:40:53 Filepath://ppdys1108/BlackwellCup/00_Blackwell/00_3B2/Gregory-
9781405132879/appln/3B2/revises/9781405132879_4_T.3d


intermediate inputs for their production. They
also require a number of discrete, separate
functions to be performed as part of the overall
production process. Williamson argued that
the extent to which all of these operations are
performed within a single vertically integrated
firm versus the extent to which some or all of
the required inputs are produced by other
firms and then acquired through a market
transaction depends on which mode of
organization most successfully minimizes
transaction costs: ‘whether a set of transac-
tions ought to be executed across markets or
within a firm depends on the relatively effi-
ciency of each mode’ (p. 8). Generally, the
more difficult or expensive the task of coord-
ination or ‘governance’ of the production pro-
cess, Williamson proposed, the greater the
likelihood that production will be vertically
integrated within a single internal hierarchy.
The geographical significance of transaction
costs (other than transportation costs) was first
made clear by Scott (1988c), who demon-
strated both theoretically and empirically that
the spatial clustering of firms often serves to
reduce the cost of transactions between them
(see cluster;industrial district). Under
such conditions, firms will find it cheaper and
easier to acquire the requisite information con-
cerning potential suppliers and buyers nearby.
Moreover, because such firms may be managed
by individuals who have come into contact with
one another repeatedly over extended periods
of time, they may have built up a high degree
of familiarity andtrustbetween them that
serves to facilitate the sharing of information
and the successful achievement of non-routine
transactions (Harrison, 1992; Nootebloom,
2006) – what Storper (1997b) called ‘untraded
interdependencies’. When such circumstances
prevail, Scott argued, one should expect to find
a much more fully articulated socialdivision
of labour, in which individual firms specialize
in the production of a relatively small number
of goods and/or services and trade actively with
one another. Such arrangements are likely to
be specially useful in industries for which mar-
ket tastes are changing rapidly, and in which
product life cyclesare short. Since input
requirements for such goods will also change
rapidly, spatial concentration will reduce the
transaction costs associated with producers
finding and assessing the performance charac-
teristics of potential new suppliers. Similarly,
when the product is complex or highly custom-
ized, it is advantageous for producers and users
to interact frequently and easily. Possibilities
for achieving this are enhanced when the

producer and user are close to one another,
thereby reducing the cost of such a complex
transaction (Lundvall, 1988).
Hence, as Storper (1997, pp. 34–5) ob-
served, this kind of analysis demonstrates
‘thatgeographyfigures in transaction costs
in general, and hence influences the boundar-
ies of the firm and production system’. He also
concluded that ‘the geography of transaction
costs helps explainagglomerationand spa-
tial divisions of labour’. However, the transac-
tion cost approach has been criticized for its
rather reductionist analysis of industrial or-
ganization – for its ‘exclusive focus on the
transaction rather than the relationship’
(Powell, 1990, p. 323) – and for its tendency
to ignore the influence of the public sector in
shaping the institutions (such as markets) that
mediateexchange(Harrison, 1997). msg

transactional analysis Ineconomic geog-
raphy, a method of determining the number
of firms in an industry and the nature of
exchanges between them. It is based on
the proposition that ‘the economic institutions
ofcapitalism have the main purpose and
effect of economizing ontransaction costs’
(Williamson, 1985, p. 17). Thus it may be
cheaper for a firm to produce acommodity
‘in-house’ through aninternal transaction,in
order to exploit internaleconomies of scope
or to reap internaleconomies of scale,orit
may be cheaper for a firm to acquire the same
commodity through an external transaction
(e.g. subcontracting), the cost of which may
be reduced by the clustering of suppliers
near to the firm (seecluster). This type of
analysis illuminates one of the forces said
to propel theagglomerationof productive
activities. Transactional analysis is also an ap-
proach used in psychology and psychotherapy;
advertised as explicitly post-Freudian, trans-
actional analysis in this second sense places
its focus on interpersonal interactions (cf.
psychoanalytic theory). Approaches of this
kind, so Bondi (1999) argued, suggest various
affinities with some versions ofhumanistic
geography. msg/dg

transculturation The entwining and entan-
gling of different cultural forms and practices
to produce new ones (cf.hybridity). The
term was originally proposed by Cuban eth-
nographer Fernando Ortiz (1881–1969), who
contrasted transculturation to acculturation.
Acculturationinvolves the adjustment of a sub-
ordinate culture to the impositions and exac-
tions of a dominant culture, a process of

Gregory / The Dictionary of Human Geography 9781405132879_4_T Final Proof page 768 31.3.2009 9:40pm Compositor Name: ARaju

TRANSACTIONAL ANALYSIS
Free download pdf