1 Advances in Political Economy - Department of Political Science

(Sean Pound) #1

EDITOR’S PROOF


A Heteroscedastic Spatial Model of the Vote 357

277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322

of different functions, but for the sake of our example we can use a simple parabola
(e.g. a quadratic approximation) estimating the convexity of lenses or the projection
of a ray of light on a parabolic mirror.
As an illustrating example, let us use the case of the Republican Party in the
U.S. In the modelLiRdescribes the reported location of the Republican Party by
respondenti. The self-reported ideological position of the same respondent is given
byxi. The quadratic approximation is thus

LiR=a+bxi+cx^2 i. (1)

We can center the convex lens of the Republican Party at its projected axis; that is,
where there exists an individualxi∗that observes the “true” location of the Republi-
can Party, designatedL∗iR, from a position perpendicular to the principal ideological
axis on which theNrespondents—each with a different image ofR’s position—are
arrayed. This allows us to setL∗iR=x∗i. With this equality, we can use (1)tosolve
forxi∗. The solution is

L∗iR=xi∗=−

1
2

− 1 +b+


1 − 2 b+b^2 − 4 ca
c

. (2)


When voting for the party, all respondentsxi=xi∗observe images that are either
closer to or further away fromLiR=L∗iDfor everyxi=xi∗, e.g. magnification.
We can describe thismagnification(M)ofthemirrorthatiattaches toRas:

MiR=

(xi−LiR)^2
(xi−L∗iR)^2

. (3)


Note that magnification is defined as the ratio of two quadratic (Euclidian) distances:
the distance from the voter’s position and her perception of the candidate’s position,
and the distance from the voter’s position to the “true” location of the party. We can
think of the first of these as “reported distance” and the second as “true distance.”
Thus, whenM>1 we have a lens thatstretchesideological, distance and when
M<1 the effect of the lens is tocompressideological distance. Moreover, if we
had information to explain the degree of magnification in reported data, we could
also estimate the “true” rather than the reported distance from the voters to the
candidates.
(
xi−L∗iR

) 2
=

(xi−LiR)^2
MiR

. (4)


While there are many different functional forms that can be used to estimate bi-
ases in the perceived location of parties, the previous example serves two purposes.
First, it provides the intuition for how we might link lessons from physics to models
of voter choice. And second, it provides a point of departure to estimate assimilation
and contrast in proximity models of voting.
Free download pdf