Private transactions between sellers and buyers start with the seller owning the
good and conclude with the buyer obtaining legal possession of the item in
exchange for payment. Besides individuals, firms and other organizations have
legal rights to undertake transactions, enter into contracts, and create new cor-
porate entities.
Private markets depend on the rule of law created and maintained by gov-
ernment and enforced by the police and the courts. Even today, property rights
can change. For instance, tradable pollution permits and rights in genomic
material are new types of property rights. Recent court rulings have held that
unauthorized downloading music over the Internet violates the property rights
of the music’s creators. In summary, well-functioning private markets could
not exist without the underpinning of government.
In Chapter 7, we showed that perfectly competitive markets are efficient,
that is, competitive markets provide the right amounts of goods and services at mini-
mum cost to the consumers who value them most highly. This is best thought of as a
benchmark. While many markets in the United States approximate the require-
ments of perfect competition, notable cases of market failure also exist. Market
failures usually can be traced to three causes: (1) the presence of monopoly
power, (2) the existence of externalities, or (3) the absence of perfect infor-
mation. In the next three sections, we examine each of these cases in turn.
MARKET FAILURE DUE TO MONOPOLY
Monopolistic markets (pure monopoly, monopolistic competition, or oligopoly)
deviate from the efficiency standard. Relative to pure competition, monopoly
power elevates prices, increasing the monopolist’s profit at the expense of con-
sumer welfare. Consumers lose more than monopolistic producers gain. Thus,
total welfare falls.
We can see this deadweight lossby turning back to Figure 8.3. Deadweight
loss is measured by the triangle MDE. The perfectly competitive outcome
(point E) delivers maximum social benefit in the form of the large consumer-
surplus triangle ACE. By contrast, under monopoly (point M), total social ben-
efit is measured as the sum of consumer surplus (triangle ABM) and the
monopolist’s excess profit (rectangle MBCD). The difference is measured by
the deadweight loss triangle MDE.
448 Chapter 11 Regulation, Public Goods, and Benefit-Cost Analysis
CHECK
STATION 1
Let industry demand be given by P 20 2Q and industry unit cost by AC MC 8.
Find output and price under pure monopoly and under perfect competition. Calculate
the deadweight loss due to monopoly.
Similar welfare outcomes occur in the intermediate cases of monopolistic com-
petition and oligopoly. When there is competition among a small number of
firms, prices are raised above the competitive level but fall short of the pure
c11RegulationPublicGoodsandBenefitCostAnalysis.qxd 9/29/11 1:34 PM Page 448