68 Finance & economics The Economist March 19th 2022
that Mr Xiang’s firm, Tsingshan, had expo
sure to short positions on the lmeof about
180,000 tonnes of nickel, which were sup
posed to benefit if prices went down. They
didn’t, as a shortcovering scramble for
nickel briefly pushed prices above
$100,000 a tonne on March 8th, putting
Tsingshan’s potential losses into the bil
lions of dollars. At that point the lmesus
pended nickel trading, cancelling all trades
that took place overnight. When the sus
pension was lifted on March 16th, a sharp
drop in nickel prices forced the lmeto sus
pend trading again, adding to the chaos.
Three big questions remain. How im
portant is Tsingshan’s role in the debacle?
Did its troubles provoke interference from
China? And has the lme bungled its re
sponse? All will be the subject of scrutiny.
In media reports, Tsingshan has the
lead role in the drama. There is debate
about whether its shortselling represent
ed the normal activity of one of the world’s
largest nickel producers hedging its out
put, or a speculator making a rash bet.
What appears clear is that the nickel it pro
duces is not the type of metallic nickel that
is traded on the lme, meaning there was a
mismatch between its shorts and longs. As
its losses increased, its brokers forced it to
provide more cash, or “margin”. The size of
its position meant that they also faced big
margin calls, making it as much their pro
blem as Tsingshan’s. On March 15th Tsing
shan said it had reached a standstill agree
ment with its creditors until it reduces its
positions in an orderly way.
In the market, rumours abound that
China may have influenced the lme’s activ
ities, partly because Hong Kong Exchanges
and Clearing (hkex) owns the exchange,
and also because Tsingshan is strategically
important to the country, because its nick
el goes into electricvehicle batteries. The
lmedenies receiving pressure from hkex.
It granted extra time on March 7th to ccbi
Global, a Chinese broker for Tsingshan that
is a member of the lme, to raise funds from
its stateowned parent, China Construc
tion Bank, to cover margin calls. That may
have been a prudent thing to do. It knew
the wealthy bank could provide the funds.
Some traders wonder whether it would
have been as tolerant with a nonChinese
entity. In the aftermath, Chinese authori
ties are said to have fought hard to stop
Tsingshan’s nickel assets falling into the
hands of nonChinese speculators.
The most intense scrutiny may fall on
the lmeitself, specifically the timing of its
decision to suspend nickel trading and the
cancelling of overnight trades that were ru
moured to be in the billions of dollars. It
said it halted trading in the early hours of
March 8th when it reckoned the nickel
market had become disorderly. It added
that its decision to cancel that day’s trades
was because the big price moves had creat
edasystemicrisktothemarket,raising
concernsofmultipledefaultsbymember
brokersstrugglingtomeetmargincalls.
Thatlatterdecisionisthebiggestbone
ofcontention.Criticssayitfavouredthose
withshortpositions,suchasphysicalpro
ducers andtheir banks,overthose with
longpositionsthatcouldbesoldata big
profit.Theyaskwhyit steppedintoprotect
brokerswhenthelmehasa defaultfund
thatitsmemberscangetaccesstointimes
oftrouble.“Thedecisiontoerasethetra
des...willunderminelongtermconfidence
inthelme,” saysYaoHuaOoiofaqr, anas
setmanagerthathadtradescancelledon
March8th.“Ifyouwanttheaqrs ofthis
world[inthemarket],youcannotinter
venewhentheymakemoneyandithurts
yourbrokers.”Hesaidthefirmwasexplor
ingalloptionsagainstthelme.
Thelmehassincesetdailylimitson
price moves (which were exceeded on
March16thwhenit brieflyreopenednickel
trading).Thatisanothersignof interven
tionbyanexchangethatusedtoprideit
selfonitsfreemarketnature.Itsownerin
Hong Kong,withChinalookingoverits
shoulder,wouldnodoubtapprove.n
Windfalltaxes
Power grab
O
n march8th, the day the price of a bar
rel of Brent crude oil spiked above $127,
the European Commission unveiled its
grand plan to fight stratospheric living
costs. Claiming that the “crisis situation”
warranted exceptional measures, it recom
mended that member states levy a oneoff
tax on electricitygenerating firms. The
revenues raised could then be used to keep
households’ bills down. The next day Eliza
beth Warren, a senator from Massachu
setts, tweeted that she and other legislators
were working on a tax on the “warfuelled
profits” accruing to American oil majors.
The proposal is now making its way
through the House of Representatives.
Politicians have reached for such
“windfall” taxes before. Bulgaria, Italy, Ro
mania and Spain have imposed them on
power generators in recent months, as
benchmark energy prices have risen. In
1980 America announced that it would be
gin taxing oil producers in six years’ time,
hoping to cash in on profits that were ex
pected to be made after prices were deregu
lated. Britain’s new Labour government
taxed utilities in 1997, after the Conserva
tive government had sold them off cheaply.
The levies are understandably tempting
for the taxman. Big windfalls mean big re
ceipts. The usual worry with a tax is that it
might change companies’ behaviour, say
by encouraging them to lower investment
in order to bring down future tax bills. But
the event causing the windfall is meant to
be a oneoff, unconnected to investment.
They are “extremely efficient ways to raise
revenue”, says Helen Miller of the Institute
for Fiscal Studies, a thinktank in London.
At least, in theory.
Britain’s tax probably fitted the ideal
better than most. It had a clear rationale:
that excess gains had come from the un
derpricing of shares when firms were pri
vatised. Postprivatisation profits were
multiplied by a pricetoearnings ratio; a
23% tax was levied on what was left over
once public proceeds from privatisation
were subtracted. Even then, however, the
tax failed to target the beneficiaries of ex
cess gains. British Telecom, the first utility
to be privatised, had listed in 1984. Many
early punters had come and gone, leaving
shareholders in 1997 bearing the burden.
Levies elsewhere have faced other hur
dles. In 2006 Mongolia introduced a 68%
charge on profits from copper and gold
sales, hoping to cash in on a new mine dur
ing a commodityprice boom. Instead, in
vestors withheld funds for the project until
regulators agreed to drop the tax. Ameri
ca’s tax did distort firms’ behaviour, by
some estimates reducing oil production
between 1980 and 1986 by up to 4.8%.
The European Commission’s plan has
its flaws. It does not explain why the cur
rent situation warrants a oneoff tax, add
ing uncertainty about when such levies
might be used again. Furthermore, the en
ergy industry buys and sells power using
longterm contracts, making the link be
tween today’s prices and tomorrow’s pro
fits fuzzy. And prices can fall as quickly as
they rise. By March 16th, for instance, the
oil price was back to about $100 a barrel.
Recent experiments offer scant
grounds for optimism. Romania, Italy and
Politicians turn to a tax that is enticing
on paper, but tricky in practice
The taxman’s temptation