Introduction to Corporate Finance

(Tina Meador) #1
13: Capital Structure

insolvency costs. At higher debt levels, however, the risk of insolvency rises, and some companies may


find that the tax advantages of debt are not sufficient to risk the costs of going bankrupt. This leads to


the trade-off model of capital structure in which managers try to find the optimal balance between debt’s


various costs and benefits. The optimal balance is the one that maximises the value of the company.


Recognition of insolvency costs allows us to expand the basic valuation formula first presented in Section


13-3 to express the value of a levered company, Vl, relative to the value of an unlevered company, Vu, the


present value of the benefits from debt tax shields and the present value of expected insolvency costs:


Eq. 13.7 Vl = Vu + PV(Tax shields) – PV(Insolvency costs)


Asset Characteristics and Insolvency Costs


Intuitively, it seems that insolvency will be very costly for some types of companies and less costly


for others. For example, consider a company that sells durable goods like appliances or automobiles.


Customers may hesitate to buy the company’s products if the company is at risk of becoming insolvent,


because an insolvent company might not be able to service the products that it sells. For such a company,


the loss of customers could be a very significant indirect cost of becoming insolvent, so the company has


an incentive to be very careful about the amount of debt that it issues. On the other hand, few customers


would worry about the long-term consequences of their local grocery store becoming insolvent, because


not much service after the sale is required in that business. As a general rule, producers of sophisticated


products or services have an incentive to use less debt than companies producing simple goods or


basic services.


Companies with mostly tangible assets that have well-established secondary markets should be more


willing to use debt than companies with mostly intangible assets. Companies can use tangible assets as


collateral for loans, which may reduce the cost of borrowing, and companies can sell those assets for cash


if and when financial distress occurs. Therefore, trucking companies, airlines, construction companies,


pipeline companies and railways can all employ more debt than can companies with fewer tangible


assets, such as pharmaceutical manufacturers, food distributors (what is the collateral value of week-old


tomatoes?) and pure service companies.


Financial distress may provide managers with perverse yet rational incentives to play a variety of


games, mostly at bondholders’ expense. Two such games – asset substitution and underinvestment – are


especially damaging. Both games begin when managers realise that the company will probably not fulfil


its obligations to creditors.


The Asset Substitution Problem


To illustrate how asset substitution works, assume that a company has bonds with a face value of


$10 million outstanding that mature in 30 days. These bonds were issued years ago when the company


was prospering, but since then the company has fallen on hard times. In spite of its difficulties, the


company still has $8 million in cash on hand, and the company’s managers still control its investment


policy. The company can invest this cash in either of two available projects, both of which require a cash


investment of $8 million. Alternatively, the company can simply hold the cash in reserve to partially repay


the bond issue in 30 days. The first investment opportunity is a low-risk project (code-named ‘Boring’ by


company insiders) that will return a near-certain $8.15 million in 30 days. This is a monthly return of


1.88%, or an annual return of almost 25%. In other words, it is a positive-NPV project that will increase


company value, but it does not earn enough to fully pay off the maturing bonds.


asset substitution
When shareholders choose
risky projects that benefit
themselves but reduce the
value of bondholders

John Graham, Duke
University
‘The majority of
companies follow the
trade-off model.’
See the entire interview on
the CourseMate website.

Source: Cengage Learning

COURSEMATE
SMART VIDEO
Free download pdf