The Spartan Regime_ Its Character, Origins, and Grand Strategy - Paul Anthony Rahe

(Dana P.) #1

Land Tenure in Archaic Sparta 129


chaic period.^16 Moreover, a strikingly similar system of land tenure was later


instituted in comparable circumstances in Egypt by Ptolemy I after the death


of Alexander, and over time the system of fiefs he established in the Fayum with


an eye to providing himself and his heirs with a reliable army gave way, and a


system of private ownership corresponding to the aspirations of the landhold-


ers gradually replaced it, just as appears to have happened in Lacedaemon at


the end of the Peloponnesian War.^17


Against the supposition that prior to the mid-fifth century much of the


land at Sparta was communally owned but assigned to individual warriors ex-


pected to defend the political community, we must weigh the silence of Hero-


dotus, Thucydides, and Xenophon—which would have considerable weight


if they elsewhere showed the keen interest in systems of land tenure that is


so visible in Plato, Ephorus, and Aristotle. But such an interest they do not


evidence—which means that their silence on this matter tells us a great deal


about their predilections and next to nothing about arrangements at Sparta.^18


There is, however, one other objection to the hypothesis presented here;


and, to the unsuspecting glance, it would appear to have considerable force.


The population of Spartiates at the time of the Persian Wars was eight thou-


sand or more (Hdt. 7.234). That in Aristotle’s day was under one thousand


(Pol. 1270a29–31). Aristotle explains the dearth of Spartan manpower [olıgan­


thrōpía] in his own time with an eye to the system of private land tenure in


existence in his own day, and his argument is cogent (1270a11–18). As he


suggests, in an agrarian setting in which partitive inheritance is the norm,


family ambition really is apt to induce those with property to marry their


offspring to others similarly situated; and, where servile labor is plentiful,


partitive inheritance creates an incentive for married couples to limit child-


bearing. In consequence, property is likely to gradually become concentrated—


which, at Sparta, would result in a steady decline in the number of those eli-


gible to be citizens who possess a competence sufficient to support them in


their status as full-time warriors and to enable them to make the requisite


contribution to the sussıtía (1271a26–36). Were this demographic trend evi-


dent only after the Peloponnesian War, it would be explicable as a product of


the law of Epitadeus, and it would not be necessary to discuss the matter here.


But, in fact, the decline in the Spartan population may have been more dra-


matic in the fifth century than it was in the fourth.


In 480, there were, as we have just seen, roughly eight thousand Spartans;


and a year later, after losing two hundred ninety-eight men at Thermopylae

Free download pdf