The Economist - USA (2021-07-10)

(Antfer) #1

66 Finance & economics TheEconomistJuly10th 2021


end of the year. The Fed’s careful approach
might  reflect  lingering  memories  of  2013,
when  it  last  warned  of  tapering  to  come.
Bonds  sold  off  sharply,  the  dollar  soared
and  emerging  markets  suffered  capital
outflows in what is now known as the “tap­
er  tantrum”.  Even  Mr  Powell’s  announce­
ment in June was accompanied by a mini­
tantrum of sorts. Prompted by higher infla­
tion,  officials  also  indicated  that  they  ex­
pected  to  raise  interest  rates  twice  by  the
end  of  2023,  sooner  than  they  had  previ­
ously  signalled.  The  hawkish  turn  sent
emerging­market currencies tumbling.
qeis swathed in so much mystical un­
certainty  that  working  out  the  impact  of
unwinding it is no easy feat. But a careful
examination of central banks’ past experi­
ence  of  asset  purchases  yields  clues  for
what to expect. It also contains lessons for
how  central  banks  might  be  able  to  extri­
cate  themselves  from  their  bond­buying
gracefully  this  time,  before  the  negative
side­effects  of  their  enormous  balance­
sheets start to be felt acutely. 
Begin  with  the  effects  of  changing
course. Everyone agrees that central banks’
asset  purchases  reduce  long­term  bond
yields.  But  there  is  enormous  uncertainty
as to how much they underpin markets to­
day.  Last  year  Ben  Bernanke,  the  Fed’s
chairman at the time of the taper tantrum,
suggested  that  in  America  in  2014  every
$500bn  of  qereduced  ten­year  Treasury
yields  by  0.2  percentage  points.  By  that
rule  of  thumb,  adjusted  for  inflation,  the
Fed’s total securities holdings of $7.5trn to­
day are lowering yields by nearly three per­
centage  points  (though  Mr  Bernanke  sug­
gested, somewhat arbitrarily, that the over­
all effect of qemight be capped at 1.2 per­
centage points). 
Alternatively, the median estimate of a
survey  of  24  studies  conducted  in  2016  by
Joseph Gagnon of the Peterson Institute for
International Economics suggests that as­
set  purchases  worth  10%  of  gdpreduced
ten­year government bond yields by about
half a percentage point. That suggests that
qetoday is suppressing long­term rates by
just under two percentage points in Amer­
ica, Britain and the euro area—although Mr
Gagnon argues that when yields approach
zero, as they have in Europe and Japan, qe
reaches  its  limits.  A  bigger  bond  market
may also reduce the size of the effect. The
Bank  of  Japan  owns  government  debt
worth a staggering 97% of gdp, but Mr Gag­
non finds the effects of qe have historically
been more muted, perhaps because Japan’s
total  public  debt  is  more  than  two­and­a­
half times that figure.
These  numbers,  and  the  experience  of
the taper tantrum, make the reversal of qe
seem  like  something  that  will  upend  fi­
nancial  markets.  Sky­high  asset  prices  to­
day reflect the assumption that long­term
interest rates will stay low for a long time.

“Weknowweneedtobeverycarefulin
communicating about asset purchases,”
MrPowellacknowledgedearlierthisyear.
Yetthelessonsfromthetapertantrumare
subtler than they seem—and may even
providesomecauseforcomfort.

Whenthetoysgooutofthepram
Thetantrumof 2013 isassociatedwithMr
Bernankeraisingthesubjectofslowingthe
Fed’s paceof assetpurchases.But asset
pricesfellbecauseinvestorsbroughtfor­
wardthedateatwhichtheyexpectedthe
Fedto raiseovernight interestrates,the
traditionalleverofmonetarypolicy.The
episodesupportsthe“signalling”theoryof
qe, whichsaysthatcentralbanks’balance­
sheetsinfluencelong­termbondyieldsnot
directly,asrulesofthumbsuggest,butby
actingasa markerforfutureinterestrates.
Theimplicationisthatyoucanreverseqe
withoutmuchfussifyousevertheper­
ceivedlinkbetweenassetpurchasesand
interest­ratedecisions.
Somepastepisodesoftaperingseemto
observethisrule.Indeed,theFedhasalrea­
dyachieveda bigtapering duringtheco­
vid­19crisis.Astheseverityofthepandem­
icbecameclearandmarketspanickedin
spring2020,theFedhooveredupalmost
$1.5trnofTreasuriesinjusttwomonthsbe­
fore dramatically slowingits purchases,

whicheventuallysettledataround$80bna
month.Buttherewasnoexpectationthat
interestrateswouldsoonriseandbond
yields seemed unaffected. In a speech
GertjanVliegheoftheBankofEngland,a
proponentofthesignallingtheory,cited
this experience, which was mirroredin
Britain,asevidencethatthereislittleme­
chanicallinkbetweenbondyieldsandqe.
TheFedalsoseemedtoachievesucha
separationthelasttimeitshrankitsbal­
ance­sheetsignificantly,in 2018 and2019.
It letassetsmaturewithoutreinvestingthe
proceeds,ratherthanbysellinganything—
withnodiscernibleeffectonbondyields.
“Thepointaroundsignallingandintentis
a verysalientfeatureofhowqeoperates,”
saysa traderata bigWallStreetbank.Since
theendofMarchten­yearTreasuryyields
havedrifteddown,evenastaperingtalk
hasbecomelouder.
Perhaps,then,centralbankscanpull
offa gracefulexit.Thequestioniswhether
risinginflationandboomingmarketswill
make them impatient to reverse course
moreabruptly.Some,particularlyinBrit­
ain,arealsowaryofthreepotentialunde­
sirableeffectsofcentralbanks’balance­
sheetsbeingtoolargefortoolong.
Thefirstconcern,whichhastroubled
MrBailey,is aboutpreservingammuni­
tion.A popularviewisthatqeishighlyef­
fectiveatcalmingmarketsduringcrises
whenitisdeployedquicklyandatscale,
but hassmaller effects inmore normal
times.Thedangerofprolonginganenor­
mousmarketpresence ingood timesis
thatyourunoutofroomtoactwithforce
duringemergencies.Centralbankersusu­
allyscornthislogicwhenit isusedtoargue
forhigherinterestrates,becauseharming
theeconomytodaytorescueitlateristo
putthecartbefore thehorse.But ifqe
worksbestina crisisthenwithdrawingit
innormaltimesshouldnotbesopainful.
Notdoingsomightmeana gradualratchet­
ingup,duringeachcrisis,oftheshareof
governmentdebtthatcentralbanksown.
Thesecondworryistheunseemlytan­
gleofmonetaryandfiscalpolicythatqe
creates. During the pandemic central
bankshaveroutinelyfacedtheaccusation
thatqeismeanttofundgovernments;in
Januarya surveybytheFinancialTimesof
the 18 biggest investors in Britain’s gilt
marketfoundthatthe“overwhelmingma­
jority”thoughtthepurposeoftheBankof
England’sbond­buyingwastofinancethe
government’semergencyspending,rather
thantosupporttheeconomy.
Butalthoughlowerbondyieldshelpthe
government’sfinances,qedoesnotextin­
guishthegovernment’sfinancingcosts.It
justshiftsthemtocentralbanks,whose
profitsandlossesendupbackwiththetax­
payer.Thecentral­bankreservescreatedto
buybondscarrya floatingrateofinterest,
makingthemanalogoustoshort­termgov­

Shopping spree
Asset purchases by central banks, $trn
Developed markets

Source:JPMorganChase

1

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
22152009

Stock

F’CAST

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
22152009

Annual flow

F’CAST

Treasury trove
Government debt held by central banks
July 2nd 2021 or latest available

Sources:Nationalstatistics;
HaverAnalytics;TheEconomist *201figures

2

United
States

Britain

Euroarea

Japan

50250

%ofbondsoutstanding
100500

% of nominal GDP*
Free download pdf