The Mathematics of Financial Modelingand Investment Management

(Brent) #1

14-Arbitrage Page 417 Wednesday, February 4, 2004 1:08 PM


Arbitrage Pricing: Finite-State Models 417

Y = dQ
---------
dP

It is clear from the definition that P and Q are equivalent probabil-
ity measures as they assign probability zero to the same events. Note
that in the case of a finite-state probability space the new probability
measure is defined on each state and is equal to

qω = Y ()ωpω

Suppose πt is a state-price deflator. Let Q be the probability measure
defined by the Radon-Nikodym derivative:

πTR 0 ,T
ξT = -------------------
π 0

The new state probabilities under Q are the following:

πT ()ω R 0 ,T
qω = ----------------------------pω
π 0 () ω

Define the density process ξt for Q as ξt= Et[ξT]. As ξt = Et[ξT] is an
adapted process, we can write:

pω ()R 0 ,T
ξT A
kt
ω ∈AktPAkt)

(Et[]) = ξAkt = ∑ -----------------ξT ()ω = ∑ ----------------- ----------------------------

pω πT ω
( ω ∈A ( ()
kt
PAkt) π 0 ω
πA
kt
R 0 ,t 1 pω

= --------------------- ---------- ∑ -----------------πT[π 0 ()ω]RtT, = ---------------------

πAktR 0 ,t

π 0 ()ω πAkt ω ∈A (
kt
PAkt) π 0

As Rt,s = (dtdt + 1...ds – 1) is the payoff at time s of one dollar invested in
a risk-free asset at time t, s > t, we can then write the following equations:

1
1 = -----Et[πsRts, ]
πt

Therefore,
Free download pdf