Dollinger index

(Kiana) #1
Notes 547


  1. The World Commission on Environment,
    1987. Retrieved from the Web February 6,
    2007. http://www.wsu.edu:8080/~sus-
    dev/WCED87.html.

  2. Comments by Frank Popoff, CEO and chair-
    man of Dow Chemical Company, at the
    Graduate Business Conference, Indiana
    University, Bloomington, Indiana, April 3,
    1992,

  3. “General Electric and Dow Jones Announce
    Winner of Economics: The Environmental
    Business Plan Challenge Award: Recipient
    Received $50,000 for Innovative
    Environmentally Friendly Plan,” 2006.
    Retrieved from the Web May 10, 2006.
    http://online.wsj.com/.

  4. The story is an old one and often makes the
    rounds in graduate economics classes.
    However, I was reminded of it by reading S.
    Oster, Modern Competitive Analysis (New
    York: Oxford University Press, 1990).

  5. A frequently heard question when one is
    challenging a new venture opportunity is: If
    this is such a good idea, why has not some-
    one already done it? As we can see, this is
    actually an economic question in sheep’s
    clothing. The correct answer to this line of
    questioning is: Because no one else has been
    smart enough, until now.

  6. C. Montgomery and B. Wernerfelt, “What Is
    an Attractive Industry?” Management Science
    32, 1986: 1223–1230.

  7. These three strategies are known as generic
    strategies because other strategies derive from
    them. Porter originally argued that a firm
    must choose to pursue one of the three strate-
    gies because it could not adhere to more than
    one strategy within a single market. He called
    this being “stuck in the middle.” Empirical
    research has demonstrated that sometimes
    firms can achieve differentiation and the low-
    cost position simultaneously. C. Hill,
    “Differentiation Versus Low Cost or Differ-
    entiation and Low Cost: A Contingency
    Framework,” Academy of Management Review
    13, 1988: 401–412; A. Murray,, “A Con-
    tingency View of Porter’s Generic
    Strategies,” Academy of Management Review
    13, 1988: 390–400; P. Wright, “A Re-
    finement of Porter’s Strategies,” Strategic
    Management Journal 9, 1980: 93–101.

  8. This is the model developed and popularized
    by Michael Porter in his two books,
    Competitive Strategy (New York: Free Press,


1980), and Competitive Advantage (New
York: Free Press, 1985). Although this chap-
ter borrows heavily from these two books
and uses the Porter analysis to examine the
problems of new venture creation, there is
really no substitute for reading the originals.


  1. We often hear the argument that quality
    improvements pay for themselves, either by
    increasing customer loyalty or increasing the
    customer base. This argument may be true if
    the increased loyalty leads to more price elas-
    ticity of demand, and if the cost increases can
    be passed on to the new customers.

  2. There are some interesting counterexamples,
    however. When competition heats up in the
    automobile industry, factory rebates (price
    concessions from manufacturers), plus the
    normal bargaining process within the dealer-
    ships, can produce final sales prices lower
    than the average variable cost for the combi-
    nation of manufacturer and dealer. In an
    overheated housing market, buyers often bid
    up the price of the house against each other
    instead of bargaining for lower prices. Such
    bargaining may occur even if the supply of
    houses is greater than the demand. It is the
    inflationary expectations that drive this
    process. People feel that the prices will be
    even higher if they do not buy quickly. Of
    course, this is a self-fulfilling prophesy for the
    group of buyers, even if it benefits a particu-
    lar buyer.

  3. This is especially true when a third party is
    paying for the airline ticket (for example, an
    employer), but the flyer receives private cred-
    it for the miles.

  4. See Porter, 1980.

  5. The presence of entry barriers is prima facie
    evidence that perfect competition does not
    exist. But does actual entry have to occur to
    keep incumbents from earning above-normal
    returns? It can be argued that the threat of
    entry is itself sufficient, as long as that entry
    is relatively costless and irreversible. This the-
    ory, the contestability theory, makes a distinc-
    tion between competitive markets, where
    actual entry enforces price discipline, and
    contestable markets, where the threat of entry
    enforces discipline even though the industry
    looks like an oligopoly. See W. Baumol, J.
    Panzer, and R. Willig, Contestable Markets
    and the Theory of Industry Structure (New
    York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, 1982).

  6. The general model to determine if entry will

Free download pdf