cost could decrease without changing the firm’s optimal price. (Small shifts in
demand that retain the kink at P* would also leave the firm’s optimal price
unchanged.) In short, each firm’s price remains constant over a range of chang-
ing market conditions. The result is stable industry-wide prices.
The kinked demand curve model presumes that the firm determines its
price behavior based on a prediction about its rivals’ reactions to potential
price changes. This is one way to inject strategic considerations into the firm’s
decisions. Paradoxically, the willingness of firms to respond aggressively to price
cuts is the very thing that sustains stable prices. Price cuts will not be attempted
if they are expected to beget other cuts. Unfortunately, the kinked demand
curve model is incomplete. It does not explain why the kink occurs at the price
P*. Nor does it justify the price-cutting behavior of rivals. (Price cutting may not
be in the best interests of these firms. For instance, a rival may prefer to hold
to its price and sacrifice market share rather than cut price and slash profit
margins.) A complete model needs to incorporate a richer treatment of strate-
gic behavior.
368 Chapter 9 Oligopoly
CHECK
STATION 2
An oligopolist’s demand curve is P 30 Q for Q smaller than 10 and P 36
1.6Q for Q greater than or equal to 10. Its marginal cost is 7. Graph this kinked
demand curve and the associated MR curve. What is the firm’s optimal output? What
if MC falls to 5?
Price Wars and the Prisoner’s Dilemma
Stable prices constitute one oligopoly outcome, but not the only one. In many
markets, oligopolists engage in vigorous price competition. To this topic we
now turn.
A surprising number of product lines are dominated by two firms, so-called
duopolists. Some immediate examples are Pepsi versus Coke, Nike versus
Reebok (running shoes), Procter & Gamble versus Kimberly-Clark (disposable
diapers), and Disney-MGM versus Universal (movie theme parks). When the
competing goods or services are close substitutes, price is a key competitive
weapon and usually the most important determinant of relative market shares
and profits.
A PRICE WAR As a concrete example, consider a pair of duopolists engaged
in price competition. To keep things simple, suppose that each duopolist can
produce output at a cost of $4 per unit: AC MC $4. Furthermore, each
firm has only two pricing options: charge a high price of $8 or charge a low
price of $6. If both firms set high prices, each can expect to sell 2.5 million
units annually. If both set low prices, each firm’s sales increase to 3.5 million
c09Oligopoly.qxd 9/29/11 1:32 PM Page 368